1932

Abstract

Infectious diseases, ideas, new products, and other infectants spread in epidemic fashion through social contact. The COVID-19 pandemic, the proliferation of fake news, and the rise of antimicrobial resistance have thrust economic epidemiology into the forefront of public policy debate and reinvigorated the field. Focusing for concreteness on disease-causing pathogens, this review provides a taxonomy of economic-epidemic models, emphasizing both the biology/immunology of the disease and the economics of the social context. An economic epidemic is one whose diffusion through the agent population is generated by agents’ endogenous behavior. I highlight properties of the equilibrium epidemic trajectory and discuss ways in which public health authorities can change the game for the better by () imposing restrictions on agent activity to reduce the harm done during a viral outbreak and () enabling diagnostic-informed interventions to slow or even reverse the rise of antibiotic resistance.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-082120-122900
2021-08-05
2024-04-19
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/economics/13/1/annurev-economics-082120-122900.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-082120-122900&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Acemoglu D, Chernozhukov V, Werning I, Whinston MD. 2020a. A multi-risk SIR model with optimally targeted lockdown NBER Work. Pap. 27102
  2. Acemoglu D, Makhdoumi A, Malekian A, Ozdaglar A. 2020b. Testing, voluntary social distancing and the spread of an infection NBER Work. Pap. 27483
  3. Adda J. 2016. Economic activity and the spread of viral diseases: evidence from high frequency data. Q. J. Econ. 131:2891–941
    [Google Scholar]
  4. Alvarez F, Argente D, Lippi F. 2021. A simple planning problem for COVID-19 lockdown, testing, and tracing. Am. Econ. Rev. Insights. In press
    [Google Scholar]
  5. Anderson ST, Laxminarayan R, Salant SW. 2012. Diversify or focus? Spending to combat infectious diseases when budgets are tight. J. Health Econ. 31:4658–75
    [Google Scholar]
  6. Auld MC. 2003. Choices, beliefs, and infectious disease dynamics. J. Health Econ. 22:3361–77
    [Google Scholar]
  7. Avery C, Bossert W, Clark A, Ellison G, Ellison SF. 2020a. An economist's guide to epidemiology models of infectious disease. J. Econ. Perspect. 34:479–104
    [Google Scholar]
  8. Avery C, Bossert W, Clark A, Ellison G, Ellison SF. 2020b. Policy implications of models of the spread of Coronavirus: perspectives and opportunities for economists. Covid Econ. 12:21–68
    [Google Scholar]
  9. Balázs É, Guillemette Y, Murtin F, Turner D. 2021. Walking the tightrope: avoiding a lockdown while containing the virus. Covid Econ. 64:101–34
    [Google Scholar]
  10. Banerjee AV. 1992. A simple model of herd behavior. Q. J. Econ. 107:3797–817
    [Google Scholar]
  11. Banerjee AV. 1993. The economics of rumours. Rev. Econ. Stud. 60:2309–27
    [Google Scholar]
  12. Bassetti S, Battegay M. 2004. Staphylococcus aureus infections in injection drug users: risk factors and prevention strategies. Infection 32:3163–69
    [Google Scholar]
  13. Basu P, Bell C, Edwards T. 2020. COVID social distancing and the poor: an analysis of the evidence for England. Covid Econ. 45:77–110
    [Google Scholar]
  14. Bauch CT, Earn DJ 2004. Vaccination and the theory of games. PNAS 101:3613391–94
    [Google Scholar]
  15. Bauch CT, Galvani AP, Earn DJ 2003. Group interest versus self-interest in smallpox vaccination policy. PNAS 100:1810564–67
    [Google Scholar]
  16. Begley S. 2020. If everyone wore a mask, Covid-19 would be brought under control, CDC director urges. STAT July 14
    [Google Scholar]
  17. Bethune ZA, Korinek A. 2020. Covid-19 infection externalities: trading off lives versus livelihoods. Covid Econ. 11:1–34
    [Google Scholar]
  18. Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welch I 1992. A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades. J. Political Econ. 100:5992–1026
    [Google Scholar]
  19. Bootsma MC, Ferguson NM 2007. The effect of public health measures on the 1918 influenza pandemic in US cities. PNAS 104:187588–93
    [Google Scholar]
  20. Brauer F, Castillo-Chavez C, Castillo-Chavez C. 2012. Mathematical Models in Population Biology and Epidemiology 2 New York: Springer
  21. Brotherhood L, Kircher P, Santos C, Tertilt M. 2020. An economic model of the Covid-19 epidemic: the importance of testing and age-specific policies IZA Discuss. Pap. 13265 Inst. Labor Econ. Bonn, Ger:.
  22. book 2013. Antibiotic Resistance Threats in the United States, 2013. Atlanta, GA: CDC http://www.cdc.gov/drugresistance/pdf/ar-threats-2013-508.pdf
  23. Chan TY, Hamilton BH, Papageorge NW. 2016. Health, risky behaviour and the value of medical innovation for infectious disease. Rev. Econ. Stud. 83:41465–510
    [Google Scholar]
  24. Chen F. 2004. Rational behavioral response and the transmission of STDs. Theor. Popul. Biol. 66:4307–16
    [Google Scholar]
  25. Chen F. 2006. A susceptible-infected epidemic model with voluntary vaccinations. J. Math. Biol. 53:2253–72
    [Google Scholar]
  26. Chen F. 2012. A mathematical analysis of public avoidance behavior during epidemics using game theory. J. Theor. Biol. 302:18–28
    [Google Scholar]
  27. Chen F, Toxvaerd F. 2014. The economics of vaccination. J. Theor. Biol. 363:105–17
    [Google Scholar]
  28. Chotiner I. 2020. Paul Romer's case for nationwide coronavirus testing. New Yorker May 3
    [Google Scholar]
  29. Cochrane JC. 2020. An SIR model with behavior. The Grumpy Economist May 4. https://johnhcochrane.blogspot.com/2020/05/an-sir-model-with-behavior.html
    [Google Scholar]
  30. Cressman R, Křivan V, Garay J. 2004. Ideal free distributions, evolutionary games, and population dynamics in multiple-species environments. Am. Nat. 164:4473–89
    [Google Scholar]
  31. Dall'Antonia M, Coen P, Wilks M, Whiley A, Millar M. 2005. Competition between methicillin-sensitive and -resistant Staphylococcus aureus in the anterior nares. J. Hosp. Infect. 61:162–67
    [Google Scholar]
  32. Deb R, Pai M, Vohra A, Vohra R. 2020. Testing alone is insufficient. Work. Pap., Univ. Toronto Toronto:
  33. DeBrabander F. 2020. The great irony of America's armed anti-lockdown protesters. Atlantic May 13
    [Google Scholar]
  34. Del Valle S, Hethcote H, Hyman JM, Castillo-Chavez C. 2005. Effects of behavioral changes in a smallpox attack model. Math. Biosci. 195:2228–51
    [Google Scholar]
  35. Dixit A. 2020. R0for Covid research: an early estimate and policy implications. Work. Pap., Princeton Univ. Princeton, NJ:
  36. Ekdahl K, Hansson HB, Mölstad S, Sóderström M, Walder M, Persson K. 1998. Limiting the spread of penicillin-resistant Streptococcus pneumoniae: experiences from the South Swedish Pneumococcal Intervention Project. Microb. Drug Resist. 4:299–105
    [Google Scholar]
  37. Eksin C, Paarporn K, Weitz JS. 2019. Systematic biases in disease forecasting—the role of behavior change. Epidemics 27:96–105
    [Google Scholar]
  38. Ellison G. 2020. Implications of heterogeneous SIR models for analyses of COVID-19. Covid Econ. 53:1–32
    [Google Scholar]
  39. Fang H, Wang L, Yang Y 2020. Human mobility restrictions and the spread of the Novel Coronavirus (2019-nCoV) in China NBER Work. Pap. 26906
  40. Farboodi M, Jarosch G, Shimer R. 2020. Internal and external effects of social distancing in a pandemic. Covid Econ. 9:1–21
    [Google Scholar]
  41. Fine P, Clarkson J. 1986. Individual versus public priorities in the determination of optimal vaccination policies. Am. J. Epidemiol. 124:61012–20
    [Google Scholar]
  42. Forsyth O. 2020. Uncertainty and lockdown in COVID-19: an incomplete information SIR model. Covid Econ. 52:1–38
    [Google Scholar]
  43. Gans J. 2020a. Test sensitivity for infection versus infectiousness of SARS-CoV-2. Covid Econ. 47:1–16
    [Google Scholar]
  44. Gans J. 2020b. The economic consequences of = 1: towards a workable behavioural epidemiological model of pandemics. Covid Econ. 41:28–51
    [Google Scholar]
  45. Geoffard PY, Philipson T. 1996. Rational epidemics and their public control. Int. Econ. Rev. 37:3603–24
    [Google Scholar]
  46. Geoffard PY, Philipson T. 1997. Disease eradication: private versus public vaccination. Am. Econ. Rev. 87:1222–30
    [Google Scholar]
  47. Gersovitz M. 2011. The economics of infection control. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 3:277–96
    [Google Scholar]
  48. Glaeser EL, Gorback CS, Redding SJ. 2020. How much does COVID-19 increase with mobility? Evidence from New York and four other US cities. J. Urban Econ. In press. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2020.103292
    [Crossref] [Google Scholar]
  49. Goolsbee A, Syverson C. 2021. Fear, lockdown, and diversion: comparing drivers of pandemic economic decline 2020. J. Public Econ. 193:104311
    [Google Scholar]
  50. Greenwood J, Kircher P, Santos C, Tertilt M. 2019. An equilibrium model of the African HIV/AIDS epidemic. Econometrica 87:41081–113
    [Google Scholar]
  51. Hendrix MJ, Walde C, Findley K, Trotman R. 2020. Absence of apparent transmission of SARS-CoV-2 from two stylists after exposure at a hair salon with a universal face covering policy—Springfield, Missouri, May 2020. Morb. Mortal. Wkly. Rep. 69:28930–32
    [Google Scholar]
  52. Hethcote H, Zhien M, Shengbing L. 2002. Effects of quarantine in six endemic models for infectious diseases. Math. Biosci. 180:1–2141–60
    [Google Scholar]
  53. Holden R, Thornton D. 2020. The stochastic reproduction rate of a virus. Covid Econ. 41:100–28
    [Google Scholar]
  54. Hoy M, Polborn MK. 2015. The value of technology improvements in games with externalities: a fresh look at offsetting behavior. J. Public Econ. 131:12–20
    [Google Scholar]
  55. Hyde TB, Gilbert M, Schwartz SB, Zell ER, Watt JP et al. 2001. Azithromycin prophylaxis during a hospital outbreak of Mycoplasma pneumoniae pneumonia. J. Infect. Dis. 183:6907–12
    [Google Scholar]
  56. Jackson MO, López-Pintado D. 2013. Diffusion and contagion in networks with heterogeneous agents and homophily. Netw. Sci. 1:149–67
    [Google Scholar]
  57. Jackson MO, Malladi S, McAdams D. 2021. Learning through the grapevine: the impact of noise and the breadth and depth of social networks. Work. Pap., Stanford Univ. Stanford, CA:
  58. Jones C, Philippon T, Venkateswaran V. 2020. Optimal mitigation policies in a pandemic: social distancing and working from home NBER Work. Pap. 26984
  59. Katriel G, Stone L. 2012. Attack rates of seasonal epidemics. Math. Biosci. 235:156–65
    [Google Scholar]
  60. Keppo J, Kudlyak M, Quercioli E, Smith L, Wilson A 2020. The behavioral SIR model, with applications to the swine flu and COVID-19 pandemics Presentation given at the STICERD Economic Theory Seminars Lond. Sch. Econ. Political Sci London: https://www.lonessmith.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/BSIRslides-June.pdf
  61. Kermack WO, McKendrick AG. 1927. A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. 115:772700–21
    [Google Scholar]
  62. Kremer M. 1996. Integrating behavioral choice into epidemiological models of AIDS. Q. J. Econ. 111:2549–73
    [Google Scholar]
  63. Lakdawalla D, Sood N, Goldman D. 2006. HIV breakthroughs and risky sexual behavior. Q. J. Econ. 121:31063–102
    [Google Scholar]
  64. Laxminarayan R, Brown GM. 2001. Economics of antibiotic resistance: a theory of optimal use. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 42:183–206
    [Google Scholar]
  65. Laxminarayan R, Duse A, Wattal C, Zaidi AK, Wertheim HF et al. 2013. Antibiotic resistance—the need for global solutions. Lancet Infect. Dis. 13:121057–98
    [Google Scholar]
  66. Makris M, Toxvaerd F. 2020. Great expectations: social distancing in anticipation of pharmaceutical innovations. Covid Econ. 56:1–19
    [Google Scholar]
  67. Manfredi P, D'Onofrio A. 2013. Modeling the Interplay Between Human Behavior and the Spread of Infectious Diseases New York: Springer
  68. McAdams D. 2014. Game-Changer: Game Theory and the Art of Transforming Strategic Situations. New York: W.W. Norton
  69. McAdams D. 2017. Resistance diagnosis and the changing epidemiology of antibiotic resistance. Ann. N. Y. Acad. Sci. 1388:15–17
    [Google Scholar]
  70. McAdams D. 2020a. Economic epidemiology in the wake of Covid-19. Covid Econ. 48:1–45
    [Google Scholar]
  71. McAdams D. 2020b. Nash SIR: an economic-epidemiological model of strategic behavior during a viral epidemic. Covid Econ. 16:115–34
    [Google Scholar]
  72. McAdams D, Day T. 2020. The political economy of a viral epidemic. Work. Pap., Duke Univ. Durham, NC:
  73. McAdams D, Song Y 2020a. Strategic social distancing with coordination motives Work. Pap., Duke Univ. Durham, NC:
  74. McAdams D, Song Y. 2020b. Viral social learning Work. Pap., Duke Univ. Durham, NC:
  75. McAdams D, Wollein Waldetoft K, Tedijanto C, Lipsitch M, Brown SP 2019. Resistance diagnostics as a public health tool to combat antibiotic resistance: a model-based evaluation. PLOS Biol. 17:5e3000250
    [Google Scholar]
  76. Meyers LA, Newman ME, Martin M, Schrag S. 2003. Applying network theory to epidemics: control measures for Mycoplasma pneumoniae outbreaks. Emerg. Infect. Dis. 9:2204–10
    [Google Scholar]
  77. Milgrom P, Roberts J. 1990. Rationalizability, learning, and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities. Econometrica 58:61255–77
    [Google Scholar]
  78. Mitchell J. 2020. State shutdowns have taken at least a quarter of U.S. economy offline. Wall Street Journal April 5
    [Google Scholar]
  79. Moisse K. 2012. Antibiotic resistance could bring “end of modern medicine. .” ABC News, March 16
    [Google Scholar]
  80. Newman ME. 2002. Spread of epidemic disease on networks. Phys. Rev. E 66:1016128
    [Google Scholar]
  81. Perisic A, Bauch CT. 2009. Social contact networks and disease eradicability under voluntary vaccination. PLOS Comput. Biol. 5:2e1000280
    [Google Scholar]
  82. Philipson T. 2000. Economic epidemiology and infectious diseases. Handbook of Health Economics 1 AJ Culyer, JP Newhouse 1761–99 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  83. Philipson TJ, Posner RA. 1993. Private Choices and Public Health: The AIDS Epidemic in an Economic Perspective Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
  84. Prakash BA, Chakrabarti D, Valler NC, Faloutsos M, Faloutsos C. 2012. Threshold conditions for arbitrary cascade models on arbitrary networks. Knowl. Inform. Syst. 33:3549–75
    [Google Scholar]
  85. Quercioli E, Smith L. 2006. Contagious matching games Work. Pap., Univ. Tex. Rio Grande Valley Edinburg:
  86. Reluga TC. 2010. Game theory of social distancing in response to an epidemic. PLOS Comput. Biol. 6:5 https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pcbi.1000793
    [Crossref] [Google Scholar]
  87. Reluga TC. 2013. Equilibria of an epidemic game with piecewise linear social distancing cost. Bull. Math. Biol. 75:101961–84
    [Google Scholar]
  88. book 2014. Antimicrobial resistance: tackling a crisis for the future health and wealth of nations. AMR Rev. Pap., UK Dep. Health London:
  89. book 2016. Tackling drug-resistant infections globally: final report and recommendations AMR Rep., UK Dep. Health London:
  90. Ross R. 1916. An application of the theory of probabilities to the study of a priori pathometry—part I. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. 92:638204–30
    [Google Scholar]
  91. Ross R, Hudson HP. 1917. An application of the theory of probabilities to the study of a priori pathometry—part II. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. 93:650212–25
    [Google Scholar]
  92. Rowthorn RE, Laxminarayan R, Gilligan CA. 2009. Optimal control of epidemics in metapopulations. J. R. Soc. Interface 6:411135–44
    [Google Scholar]
  93. Rowthorn RE, Maciejowski J. 2020. A cost-benefit analysis of the Covid-19 disease. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 36:S1S38–55
    [Google Scholar]
  94. Rowthorn RE, Toxvaerd F. 2012. The optimal control of infectious diseases via prevention and treatment CEPR Discuss. Pap. DP8925 Cent. Econ. Policy Res London:
  95. Roy S, Sabarwal T. 2010. Monotone comparative statics for games with strategic substitutes. J. Math. Econ. 46:5793–806
    [Google Scholar]
  96. Salanié F, Treich N. 2020. Public and private incentives for self-protection. Geneva Risk Insur. Rev. 45:104–13
    [Google Scholar]
  97. Serfling RE. 1952. Historical review of epidemic theory. Hum. Biol. 24:3145–66
    [Google Scholar]
  98. Sims C, Finnoff D. 2020. Uncertainty, hysteresis and lockdowns. Covid Econ. 54:29–61
    [Google Scholar]
  99. Solberg CO. 2000. Spread of Staphylococcus aureus in hospitals: causes and prevention. Scand. J. Infect. Dis. 32:6587–95
    [Google Scholar]
  100. Talamas E, Vohra R. 2018. Go big or go home: a free and perfectly safe but only partially effective vaccine can make everyone worse off PIER Work. Pap. 18-006 Univ. Pa. Philadelphia:
  101. Toxvaerd F. 2019. Rational disinhibition and externalities in prevention. Int. Econ. Rev. 60:41737–55
    [Google Scholar]
  102. Toxvaerd F. 2020. Equilibrium social distancing. Covid Econ. 15:110–33
    [Google Scholar]
  103. Troger T. 2020. Optimal testing and social distancing of individuals with private health signals. Covid Econ. 55:1–44
    [Google Scholar]
  104. book 2014. Antimicrobial Resistance: Global Report on Surveillance. Geneva, Switz: WHO
  105. Yamin D, Gavious A. 2013. Incentives' effect in influenza vaccination policy. Manag. Sci. 59:122667–86
    [Google Scholar]
  106. Yang JJ, Chang TW, Jiang Y, Kao HJ, Chiou BH et al. 2018. Commensal Staphylococcus aureus provokes immunity to protect against skin infection of methicillin-resistant Staphylococcus aureus. Int. J. Mol. Sci. 19:51290
    [Google Scholar]
  107. Zarocostas J. 2020. How to fight an infodemic. Lancet 395:10225676
    [Google Scholar]
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-082120-122900
Loading
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-082120-122900
Loading

Data & Media loading...

  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error