1932

Abstract

In representative democracies, a variety of rules are employed to select and retain public officials to reflect public preferences over policies. We discuss the literature on selection and retention rules for government officials, focusing on low-information offices. First, we overview the historical origins and the scope of the variation in selection and retention rules. Second, we provide conceptual frameworks for assessing the advantages and disadvantages of direct elections and discuss various factors that influence the functioning of elections. Third, we present empirical regularities. We summarize the baseline effects of the institutional variation and their interaction with factors such as media and compensation. Finally, we discuss outstanding questions on theoretical and empirical fronts, and how the digitization of government information and advances in machine learning can open up new avenues for research.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-072720-041256
2021-08-05
2024-10-03
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/economics/13/1/annurev-economics-072720-041256.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-072720-041256&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Abrams D, Galbiati R, Henry E, Philippe A. 2019.. When in Rome… on local norms and sentencing decisions. Work. Pap., Univ. Pa., Philadelphia:
    [Google Scholar]
  2. Acemoglu D, Jackson MO. 2017.. Social norms and the enforcement of laws. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 15::24595
    [Google Scholar]
  3. Adserà A, Boix C, Payne M. 2003.. Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government. . J. Law Econ. Organ. 19::44590
    [Google Scholar]
  4. Alesina A, Tabellini G. 2007.. Bureaucrats or politicians? Part I: a single policy task. . Am. Econ. Rev. 97::16979
    [Google Scholar]
  5. Alesina A, Tabellini G. 2008.. Bureaucrats or politicians? Part II: multiple policy tasks. . J. Public Econ. 92::42647
    [Google Scholar]
  6. Alt J, Bueno de Mesquita E, Rose S. 2011.. Disentangling accountability and competence in elections: evidence from U.S. term limits. . J. Politics 73::17186
    [Google Scholar]
  7. Anzia SF. 2011.. Election timing and the electoral influence of interest groups. . J. Politics 73::41227
    [Google Scholar]
  8. Anzia SF. 2014.. Timing and Turnout: How Off-Cycle Elections Favor Organized Groups. Chicago:: Univ. Chicago Press
    [Google Scholar]
  9. Ash E, MacLeod WB. 2015.. Intrinsic motivation in public service: theory and evidence from state supreme courts. . J. Law Econ. 58::863913
    [Google Scholar]
  10. Ash E, MacLeod WB. 2019.. Selection and incentive effects of elections: evidence from state supreme courts. NBER Work. Pap. 22071
    [Google Scholar]
  11. Ashworth S. 2012.. Electoral accountability: recent theoretical and empirical work. . Annu. Rev. Political Sci. 15::183201
    [Google Scholar]
  12. Ashworth S, Bueno de Mesquita E. 2008.. Electoral selection, strategic challenger entry, and the incumbency advantage. . J. Politics 70::100625
    [Google Scholar]
  13. Athey S, Imbens GW. 2019.. Machine learning methods that economists should know about. . Annu. Rev. Econ. 11::685725
    [Google Scholar]
  14. Bańbura M, Giannone D, Modugno M, Reichlin L. 2013.. Now-casting and the real-time data flow. . In Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Vol. 2A, ed. G Elliott, A Timmermann , pp. 195237. Amsterdam:: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  15. Banks JS, Sundaram RK. 1993.. Adverse selection and moral hazard in a repeated elections model. . In Political Economy: Institutions, Competition and Representation: Proceedings of the Seventh International Symposium in Economic Theory and Econometrics, ed. WA Barnett, MJ Hinich, NJ Schofield , pp. 295311. New York:: Cambridge Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  16. Bardhan P. 2002.. Decentralization of governance and development. . J. Econ. Perspect. 16::185205
    [Google Scholar]
  17. Bardhan P, Mookherjee D. 2006.. Decentralization, corruption and government accountability. . In International Handbook on the Economics of Corruption, ed. S Rose-Ackerman , pp. 16188. Northampton, MA:: Edward Elgar Publ
    [Google Scholar]
  18. Barro RJ. 1973.. The control of politicians: an economic model. . Public Choice 14::1942
    [Google Scholar]
  19. Barrows S. 2014.. Performance information and retrospective voting: evidence from a school accountability regime. Progr. Educ. Policy Gov. Work. Pap. Ser., Harvard Kennedy Sch., Cambridge, MA:
    [Google Scholar]
  20. Berdejó C, Yuchtman N. 2013.. Crime, punishment, and politics: an analysis of political cycles in criminal sentencing. . Rev. Econ. Stat. 95::74156
    [Google Scholar]
  21. Berry CR, Gersen JE. 2008.. The unbundled executive. . Univ. Chicago Law Rev. 75::1385434
    [Google Scholar]
  22. Berry CR, Gersen JE. 2011.. Election timing and public policy. . Q. J. Political Sci. 6::10335
    [Google Scholar]
  23. Berry CR, Howell W. 2007.. Accountability and local elections: rethinking retrospective voting. . J. Politics 69::84458
    [Google Scholar]
  24. Besley T. 2004.. Paying politicians: theory and evidence. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2::193215
    [Google Scholar]
  25. Besley T. 2006.. Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford, UK:: Oxford Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  26. Besley T, Case A. 1995.. Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence from gubernatorial term limits. . Q. J. Econ. 110::76998
    [Google Scholar]
  27. Besley T, Coate S. 2003.. Elected versus appointed regulators: theory and evidence. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 1::1176206
    [Google Scholar]
  28. Besley T, Folke O, Persson T, Rickne J. 2017.. Gender quotas and the crisis of the mediocre man: theory and evidence from Sweden. . Am. Econ. Rev. 107::220442
    [Google Scholar]
  29. Calabresi SG, Terrell N. 2009.. The fatally flawed theory of the unbundled executive. . Minn. Law Rev. 93::1696740
    [Google Scholar]
  30. Canes-Wrone B, Clark TS, Kelly JP. 2014.. Judicial selection and death penalty decisions. . Am. Political Sci. Rev. 108::2339
    [Google Scholar]
  31. Canes-Wrone B, Herron MC, Shotts KW. 2001.. Leadership and pandering: a theory of executive policymaking. . Am. J. Political Sci. 45::53250
    [Google Scholar]
  32. Carey JM. 2008.. Legislative Voting and Accountability. Cambridge, UK:: Cambridge Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  33. Caselli F, Morelli M. 2004.. Bad politicians. . J. Public Econ. 88::75982
    [Google Scholar]
  34. Choi H, Varian HR. 2012.. Predicting the present with Google trends. . Econ. Rec. 88::29
    [Google Scholar]
  35. Choi SJ, Gulati GM, Posner EA. 2010.. Professionals or politicians: the uncertain empirical case for an elected rather than appointed judiciary. . J. Law Econ. Organ. 26::290336
    [Google Scholar]
  36. Coate S, Knight B. 2011.. Government form and public spending: theory and evidence from US municipalities. . Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 3::82112
    [Google Scholar]
  37. Collins C, Hasan S, Ukkusuri SV. 2013.. A novel transit rider satisfaction metric: rider sentiments measured from online social media data. . J. Public Transp. 16::2145
    [Google Scholar]
  38. Colonnelli E, Prem M, Teso E. 2020.. Patronage and selection in public sector organizations. . Am. Econ. Rev. 110::307199
    [Google Scholar]
  39. Dahlerup D, Hilal Z, Kalandadze N, Kandawasvika-Nhundu R. 2014.. Atlas of Electoral Gender Quotas. Stockholm, Swed:.: Int. Inst. Democr. Elect. Assist
    [Google Scholar]
  40. Dal Bó E. 2007.. Bribing voters. . Am. J. Political Sci. 51::789803
    [Google Scholar]
  41. Dal Bó E, Finan F. 2018.. Progress and perspectives in the study of political selection. . Annu. Rev. Econ. 10::54175
    [Google Scholar]
  42. Dal Bó E, Finan F, Folke O, Persson T, Rickne J. 2017.. Who becomes a politician?. Q. J. Econ. 132::1877914
    [Google Scholar]
  43. Dal Bó E, Finan F, Rossi MA. 2013.. Strengthening state capabilities: the role of financial incentives in the call to public service. . Q. J. Econ. 128::1169218
    [Google Scholar]
  44. Dove JA. 2014.. Antitrust enforcement by state attorneys general: institutional, legal and political considerations. . Bus. Politics 16::291312
    [Google Scholar]
  45. Duch R, Przepiorka W, Stevenson R. 2015.. Responsibility attribution for collective decision makers. . Am. J. Political Sci. 59::37289
    [Google Scholar]
  46. Enikolopov R, Zhuravskaya E. 2007.. Decentralization and political institutions. . J. Public Econ. 91::226190
    [Google Scholar]
  47. Evans P, Rauch JE. 1999.. Bureaucracy and growth: a cross-national analysis of the effects of “Weberian” state structures on economic growth. . Am. Sociol. Rev. 64::74865
    [Google Scholar]
  48. Ferejohn J. 1986.. Incumbent performance and electoral control. . Public Choice 50::525
    [Google Scholar]
  49. Ferraz C, Finan F. 2009.. Motivating politicians: the impacts of monetary incentives on quality and performance. NBER Work. Pap. 14906
    [Google Scholar]
  50. Ferraz C, Finan F. 2011.. Electoral accountability and corruption: evidence from the audits of local governments. . Am. Econ. Rev. 101::1274311
    [Google Scholar]
  51. Ferreira F, Gyourko J. 2009.. Do political parties matter? Evidence from U.S. cities. . Q. J. Econ. 124::399422
    [Google Scholar]
  52. Finan F, Olken BA, Pande R. 2017.. The personnel economics of the developing state. . In Handbook of Field Experiments, Vol. II, ed. A Banerjee, E Duflo , pp. 467514. Amsterdam:: North Holland
    [Google Scholar]
  53. Gagliarducci S, Nannicini T. 2013.. Do better paid politicians perform better? Disentangling incentives from selection. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 11::36998
    [Google Scholar]
  54. Gentzkow M, Kelly B, Taddy M. 2019a.. Text as data. . J. Econ. Lit. 57::53574
    [Google Scholar]
  55. Gentzkow M, Shapiro JM. 2010.. What drives media slant? Evidence from U.S. daily newspapers. . Econometrica 78::3571
    [Google Scholar]
  56. Gentzkow M, Shapiro JM, Taddy M. 2019b.. Measuring group differences in high-dimensional choices: method and application to congressional speech. . Econometrica 87::130740
    [Google Scholar]
  57. Ginsberg J, Mohebbi MH, Patel RS, Brammer L, Smolinski MS, Brilliant L. 2009.. Detecting influenza epidemics using search engine query data. . Nature 457::101214
    [Google Scholar]
  58. Glaeser EL, Kim H, Luca M. 2021.. Nowcasting the local economy: using Yelp data to measure economic activity. . In Big Data for 21st Century Economic Statistics, ed. KG Abraham, RS Jarmin, B Moyer, MD Shapiro . Chicago:: Univ. Chicago Press. In press
    [Google Scholar]
  59. Glaeser EL, Kominers SD, Luca M, Naik N. 2018.. Big data and big cities: the promises and limitations of improved measures of urban life. . Econ. Inq. 56::11437
    [Google Scholar]
  60. Gordon SC, Huber GA. 2007.. The effect of electoral competitiveness on incumbent behavior. . Q. J. Political Sci. 2::10738
    [Google Scholar]
  61. Hall AB. 2019.. Who Wants to Run? How the Devaluing of Political Office Drives Polarization. Chicago:: Univ. Chicago Press
    [Google Scholar]
  62. Hansen S, McMahon M, Prat A. 2018.. Transparency and deliberation within the FOMC: a computational linguistics approach. . Q. J. Econ. 133::80170
    [Google Scholar]
  63. Hanssen FA. 2004a.. Is there a politically optimal level of judicial independence?. Am. Econ. Rev. 94::71229
    [Google Scholar]
  64. Hanssen FA. 2004b.. Learning about judicial independence: institutional change in the state courts. . J. Legal Stud. 33::43173
    [Google Scholar]
  65. Hessami Z. 2018.. Accountability and incentives of appointed and elected public officials. . Rev. Econ. Stat. 100::5164
    [Google Scholar]
  66. Hirano S, Snyder JM Jr. 2019.. Primary Elections in the United States. Cambridge, UK:: Cambridge Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  67. Hoover GA. 2008.. Elected versus appointed school district officials: Is there a difference in student outcomes?. Public Finance Rev. 36::63547
    [Google Scholar]
  68. Huber GA, Gordon SC. 2004.. Accountability and coercion: Is justice blind when it runs for office?. Am. J. Political Sci. 48::24763
    [Google Scholar]
  69. Iaryczower M, Lewis G, Shum M. 2013.. To elect or to appoint? Bias, information, and responsiveness of bureaucrats and politicians. . J. Public Econ. 97::23044
    [Google Scholar]
  70. book. 2019.. Council-manager form of government: what it is, how it works, and the benefits to your community. Broch., ICMA, Washington, DC:. https://icma.org/documents/council-manager-form-government-what-it-how-it-works-and-benefits-your-community-brochure
    [Google Scholar]
  71. Kogan V, Lavertu S, Peskowitz Z. 2018.. Election timing, electorate composition, and policy outcomes: evidence from school districts. . Am. J. Political Sci. 62::63751
    [Google Scholar]
  72. Kurtz KT, Cain BE, Niemi RG. 2009.. Institutional Change in American Politics: The Case of Term Limits. Ann Arbor:: Univ. Mich. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  73. La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R. 1999.. The quality of government. . J. Law Econ. Organ. 15::22279
    [Google Scholar]
  74. Larreguy H, Marshall J, Snyder JM Jr. 2020.. Publicising malfeasance: when the local media structure facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico. . Econ. J. 130::2291327
    [Google Scholar]
  75. Leal DL, Martinez-Ebers V, Meier KJ. 2004.. The politics of Latino education: the biases of at-large elections. . J. Politics 66::122444
    [Google Scholar]
  76. Levin J, Tadelis S. 2010.. Contracting for government services: theory and evidence from U.S. cities. . J. Ind. Econ. 58::50741
    [Google Scholar]
  77. Lim CSH. 2013.. Preferences and incentives of appointed and elected public officials: evidence from state trial court judges. . Am. Econ. Rev. 103::136097
    [Google Scholar]
  78. Lim CSH, Snyder JM Jr. 2015.. Is more information always better? Party cues and candidate quality in U.S. judicial elections. . J. Public Econ. 128::10723
    [Google Scholar]
  79. Lim CSH, Snyder JM Jr., Strömberg D. 2015.. The judge, the politician, and the press: newspaper coverage and criminal sentencing across electoral systems. . Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 7::10335
    [Google Scholar]
  80. Lim CSH, Yurukoglu A. 2018.. Dynamic natural monopoly regulation: time inconsistency, moral hazard, and political environments. . J. Political Econ. 126::263312
    [Google Scholar]
  81. Lucca D, Seru A, Trebbi F. 2014.. The revolving door and worker flows in banking regulation. . J. Monet. Econ. 65::1732
    [Google Scholar]
  82. Martin GJ, Yurukoglu A. 2017.. Bias in cable news: persuasion and polarization. . Am. Econ. Rev. 107::256599
    [Google Scholar]
  83. Martinez-Bravo M. 2014.. The role of local officials in new democracies: evidence from Indonesia. . Am. Econ. Rev. 104::124487
    [Google Scholar]
  84. Martinez-Bravo M, Padró I Miquel G, Qian N, Yao Y. 2017.. The rise and fall of local elections in China: theory and empirical evidence on the autocrat's trade-off. NBER Work. Pap. 24032
    [Google Scholar]
  85. Maskin E, Tirole J. 2004.. The politician and the judge: accountability in government. . Am. Econ. Rev. 94::103454
    [Google Scholar]
  86. Mattozzi A, Merlo A. 2008.. Political careers or career politicians?. J. Public Econ. 92::597608
    [Google Scholar]
  87. Messner M, Polborn MK. 2004.. Paying politicians. . J. Public Econ. 88::242345
    [Google Scholar]
  88. Mullainathan S, Spiess J. 2017.. Machine learning: an applied econometric approach. . J. Econ. Perspect. 31::87106
    [Google Scholar]
  89. Oliver JE, Ha SE, Callen Z. 2012.. Local Elections and the Politics of Small-Scale Democracy. Princeton, NJ:: Princeton Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  90. Persson T, Roland G, Tabellini G. 1997.. Separation of powers and political accountability. . Q. J. Econ. 112::1163202
    [Google Scholar]
  91. Persson T, Roland G, Tabellini G. 2000.. Comparative politics and public finance. . J. Political Econ. 108::112161
    [Google Scholar]
  92. Persson T, Tabellini G, Trebbi F. 2003.. Electoral rules and corruption. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 1::95889
    [Google Scholar]
  93. Pique R. 2019.. Higher pay, worse outcomes? The impact of mayoral wages on local government quality in Peru. . J. Public Econ. 173::120
    [Google Scholar]
  94. Provost C. 2009.. When is AG short for aspiring governor? Ambition and policy making dynamics in the office of state attorney general. . Publius J. Fed. 40::597616
    [Google Scholar]
  95. Rauch JE, Evans PB. 2000.. Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic performance in less developed countries. . J. Public Econ. 75::4971
    [Google Scholar]
  96. Rogoff K. 1985.. The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. . Q. J. Econ. 100::116989
    [Google Scholar]
  97. Saiz A, Simonsohn U. 2013.. Proxying for unobservable variables with internet document-frequency. . J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 11::13765
    [Google Scholar]
  98. Sances M. 2016.. The distributional impact of greater responsiveness: evidence from New York towns. . J. Politics 78::10519
    [Google Scholar]
  99. Sandford M. 2019.. Directly-elected mayors. Brief. Pap. 05000 , House Commons Libr., UK Parliam., London:
    [Google Scholar]
  100. Scott SL, Varian HR. 2014.. Predicting the present with Bayesian structural time series. . Int. J. Math. Model. Numer. Optim. 5::423
    [Google Scholar]
  101. Scott SL, Varian HR. 2015.. Bayesian variable selection for nowcasting economic time series. . In Economic Analysis of the Digital Economy, ed. A Goldfarb, SM Greenstein, CE Tucker , pp. 11935. Chicago:: Univ. Chicago Press
    [Google Scholar]
  102. Seamans R, Zhu F. 2014.. Responses to entry in multi-sided markets: the impact of Craigslist on local newspapers. . Manag. Sci. 60::47693
    [Google Scholar]
  103. Snyder JM Jr., Strömberg D. 2010.. Press coverage and political accountability. . J. Political Econ. 118::355408
    [Google Scholar]
  104. Snyder JM Jr., Ting MM. 2008.. Interest groups and the electoral control of politicians. . J. Public Econ. 92::482500
    [Google Scholar]
  105. Stephens-Davidowitz S. 2014.. The cost of racial animus on a black candidate: evidence using Google search data. . J. Public Econ. 118::2640
    [Google Scholar]
  106. Thompson WN. 1974.. Should we elect or appoint state government executives? Some new data concerning state attorneys general. . Midwest Rev. Public Adm. 8::1741
    [Google Scholar]
  107. Treisman D. 2007.. The Architecture of Government: Rethinking Political Decentralization. Cambridge, UK:: Cambridge Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  108. Veronese B. 2008.. How do institutions shape policy making? The transition from parliamentarism to presidentialism in Italian local governments. . In Italian Institutional Reforms: A Public Choice Perspective, ed. F Padovano, R Ricciuti , pp. 11738. New York:: Springer
    [Google Scholar]
  109. Vlaicu R, Whalley A. 2016.. Hierarchical accountability in government. . J. Public Econ. 134::8599
    [Google Scholar]
  110. Volcansek ML. 2007.. Appointing judges the European way. . Fordham Urban Law J. 34::19
    [Google Scholar]
  111. Whalley A. 2013.. Elected versus appointed policy makers: evidence from city treasurers. . J. Law Econ. 56::3981
    [Google Scholar]
  112. Wilkerson J, Casas A. 2017.. Large-scale computerized text analysis in political science: opportunities and challenges. . Annu. Rev. Political Sci. 20::52944
    [Google Scholar]
  113. Wollmann H. 2005.. The directly elected executive mayor in German local government. . In Transforming Local Political Leadership, ed. R Berg, N Rao , pp. 2941. New York:: Springer
    [Google Scholar]
  114. Xu G. 2018.. The costs of patronage: evidence from the British Empire. . Am. Econ. Rev. 198::317098
    [Google Scholar]
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-072720-041256
Loading
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-072720-041256
Loading

Data & Media loading...

  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error