1932

Abstract

Increasing consolidation and vertical coordination in the food chain have made the prospect of market power abuses by powerful food manufacturers and retailers an issue and a policy concern worldwide, in terms of potential impacts on farmer and consumer welfare and sector efficiency. We address the extent to which traditional wisdom and standard conceptual and empirical models that have girded thought about market power in the food chain for decades apply in modern food-market contexts and examine recent work on competition in the food chain to gauge the most promising paths forward. A key conclusion is that considerations that go beyond the bounds of standard models likely cause market power to be less than would be predicted based on the highly concentrated structures of many modern agricultural and food markets. These considerations include downstream buyers who rationally internalize long-run implications of their pricing decisions to farmers, powerful food manufacturers and retailers who countervail each other's market power, and the complex pricing decisions of multistore and multiproduct food retailers.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100517-023312
2018-10-05
2024-12-11
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/resource/10/1/annurev-resource-100517-023312.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100517-023312&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Adams B, Williams KR 2017. Zone pricing in regional oligopoly Discuss. Pap. 2079 Cowles Found. Res. Econ New Haven, CT:
    [Google Scholar]
  2. Adjemian M, Saitone TL, Sexton RJ 2016. A framework to analyze the performance of thinly traded agricultural commodity markets. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 98:581–96
    [Google Scholar]
  3. Agric. Mark. Task Force. 2016. Enhancing the position of farmers in the supply chain Rep., Agric. Mark. Task Force, Eur. Comm Brussels:
    [Google Scholar]
  4. Allain M-L, Chambolle C, Turolla S, Villas-Boas SB 2017. Retail mergers and food prices: evidence from France. J. Ind. Econ. 65:469–509
    [Google Scholar]
  5. Allender W, Richards T 2010. Market diversion and market power: California eggs. Rev Ind. Org. 36:37–58
    [Google Scholar]
  6. Alston JM, Sexton RJ, Zhang M 1997. The effects of imperfect competition on the size and distribution of research benefits. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 79:1252–65
    [Google Scholar]
  7. Anders SM 2008. Imperfect competition in German food retailing: evidence from state level data. Atl. Econ. J. 36:441–54
    [Google Scholar]
  8. Appelbaum E 1982. The estimation of the degree of oligopoly power. J. Econom. 19:287–99
    [Google Scholar]
  9. Atkin D, Donaldson D 2015. Who's getting globalized? The size and implications of intra-national trade costs NBER Work: Pap21439
    [Google Scholar]
  10. Azzam AM, Pagoulatos E 1990. Testing oligopolistic and oligopsonistic behavior: an application to the U.S. meat-packing industry. J. Agric. Econ. 41:362–70
    [Google Scholar]
  11. Bain JS 1956. Barriers to New Competition Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  12. Basker E 2007. The causes and consequences of Wal-Mart's growth. J. Econ. Perspect. 21:177–98
    [Google Scholar]
  13. Basker E, Noel M 2009. The evolving food chain: competitive effects of Wal-Mart's entry into the supermarket industry. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 18:977–1009
    [Google Scholar]
  14. Beggs A 1992. Mergers and malls. J. Ind. Econ. 42:419–28
    [Google Scholar]
  15. Beraja M, Hurst E, Ospina J 2016. The aggregate implications of regional business cycles NBER Work: Pap21956
    [Google Scholar]
  16. Berdegué JA, Balsevich F, Flores L, Reardon T 2005. Central American supermarkets’ private standards of quality and safety procurement of fresh fruits and vegetables. Food Policy 30:254–69
    [Google Scholar]
  17. Bergès-Sennou F, Bontems P, Réquillart V 2004. Economics of private labels: a survey of literature. J. Agric. Food Ind. Org. 2:1037–62
    [Google Scholar]
  18. Bhuyan S, Lopez RA 1997. Oligopoly power in the food and tobacco industries. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 79:1035–43
    [Google Scholar]
  19. Bliss C 1988. A theory of retail pricing. J. Ind. Econ. 36:375–91
    [Google Scholar]
  20. Bloom P, Gundlach G, Cannon J 2000. Slotting allowances and fees: schools of thought and the views of practicing managers. J. Mark. 64:92–108
    [Google Scholar]
  21. Bonnano G, Vickers J 1988. Vertical separation. J. Ind. Econ. 36:257–65
    [Google Scholar]
  22. Bonnet C, Bouamra-Mechemache Z 2016. Organic label, bargaining power, and profit-sharing in the French fluid milk market. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 98:113–33
    [Google Scholar]
  23. Bontemps C, Orozco V, Réquillart V 2008. Private labels, national brands and food prices. Rev. Ind. Org. 33:1–22
    [Google Scholar]
  24. Bontems P, Monier-Dilhan S, Réquillart V 1999. Strategic effects of private labels. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 26:147–65
    [Google Scholar]
  25. Bresnahan T 1982. The oligopoly solution is identified. Econ. Lett. 10:87–92
    [Google Scholar]
  26. Bukeviciute L, Dierx A, Ilkovitz F 2009. The functioning of the food supply chain and its effect on food prices in the European Union Eur. Econ. Occas. Pap. 47 Eur. Comm Brussels:
    [Google Scholar]
  27. Chen Z 2007. Buyer power: economic theory and antitrust policy. Res. Law Econ. 22:17–40
    [Google Scholar]
  28. Chen Z, Rey P 2012. Loss leading as an exploitative practice. Amer. Econ. Rev. 102:3462–82
    [Google Scholar]
  29. Chidmi B, Lopez RA, Cotterill RW 2005. Retail oligopoly power, dairy compact, and Boston milk prices. Agribusiness 21:477–491
    [Google Scholar]
  30. Clancy MS, Moschini G 2017. Intellectual property rights and the ascent of proprietary innovation in agriculture. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 9:53–74
    [Google Scholar]
  31. Claycombe RJ, Mahan TE 1993. Spatial aspects of retail market structure: beef pricing revisited Int. . J. Ind. Org. 11:283–91
    [Google Scholar]
  32. Cohen MA, Cotterill RW 2011. Assessing the impact of retailer store brand presence on manufacturer brands in an equilibrium framework. J. Ind. Econ. 59:372–95
    [Google Scholar]
  33. Connor JM 2008. Global Price Fixing Berlin: Springer-Verlag. , 2nd ed..
    [Google Scholar]
  34. Connor JM, Rogers RT, Marion BW, Mueller WF 1985. The Food Manufacturing Industries: Structures, Strategies, Performance, and Policies Lexington, MA: DC Heath
    [Google Scholar]
  35. Cooper D 2003. Findings from the competition commission's inquiry into supermarkets. J. Agric. Econ. 54:127–43
    [Google Scholar]
  36. Corts KS 1999. Conduct parameters and the measurement of market power. J. Econom. 88:227–50
    [Google Scholar]
  37. Cotterill RW, Putsis WP, Dhar R 2000. Assessing the competitive interaction between private labels and national brands. J. Bus. 73:109–37
    [Google Scholar]
  38. Courtois P, Subervie J 2014. Farmer bargaining power and market information services. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 97:953–77
    [Google Scholar]
  39. Cowling K, Waterson M 1976. Price-cost margins and market structure. Economica 43:267–74
    [Google Scholar]
  40. Crespi JM, Saitone TL, Sexton RJ 2012. Competition in U.S. farm product markets: Do long-run incentives trump short run market power?. App. Econ. Perspect. Policy 34:669–95
    [Google Scholar]
  41. Crespi JM, Sexton RJ 2004. Bidding for cattle in the Texas panhandle. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 86:660–74
    [Google Scholar]
  42. Crespi JM, Sexton RJ 2005. A multinomial logit framework to estimate bid shading in procurement auctions: application to cattle sales in the Texas panhandle. Rev. Ind. Org. 27:253–78
    [Google Scholar]
  43. Dai J, Wang X 2014. Is China's dairy processing industry oligopolistic and/or oligopsonistic?. China Agric. Econ. Rev. 6:644–53
    [Google Scholar]
  44. DellaVigna S, Gentzkow M 2017. Uniform pricing in U.S. retail chains NBER Work: Pap23996
    [Google Scholar]
  45. Desiraju R 2001. New product introductions, slotting allowances and retailer discretion. J. Retail. 77:335–58
    [Google Scholar]
  46. DeVuyst CS 2005. Demand screening with slotting allowances and failure fees. J. Agric. Food Ind. Org. 3:1076–93
    [Google Scholar]
  47. Dobson P, Waterson M 1997. Countervailing power and consumer prices. Econ. J. 107:418–30
    [Google Scholar]
  48. Dobson P, Waterson M 2005. Chain-store pricing across local markets. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 14:93–119
    [Google Scholar]
  49. Draganska M, Klapper D, Villas-Boas SB 2010. A larger slice or a larger pie? An empirical investigation of bargaining power in the distribution channel. Mark. Sci. 29:57–74
    [Google Scholar]
  50. Dries L, Reardon T, Swinnen JFM 2004. The rapid rise of supermarkets in central and eastern Europe: implications for the agrifood sector and rural development. Dev. Policy Rev. 22:525–556
    [Google Scholar]
  51. Einarsson Á 2007. The retail sector in the Nordic countries: a comparative analysis. Bifröst J. Soc. Sci. 1:31–42
    [Google Scholar]
  52. Ellickson PB 2007. Does Sutton apply to supermarkets?. RAND J. Econ. 38:43–59
    [Google Scholar]
  53. Eur. Comm. 2009. A better functioning food supply chain in Europe Commun. 591, Comm. Eur. Communities, Oct. 28 Eur. Comm Brussels: http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/pages/publication16061_en.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  54. Eur. Comm. 2013. Unfair trading practices in the business-to-business food and non-food supply chain in Europe Commun. 37, Jan. 31 Eur. Comm., Brussels: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52013DC0037&from=EN
    [Google Scholar]
  55. Eur. Comm. 2014. Tackling unfair trading practices in the business-to-business food supply chain Commun. 472, July 15 Eur. Comm Strasbourg: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/retail/docs/140715-communication_en.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  56. Eur. Comm. 2016. Unfair trading practices in the food supply chain Rep., Comm. Intern. Mark. Consum. Prot., May 4 Eur. Parliam Brussels: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//NONSGML+REPORT+A8-2016-0173+0+DOC+PDF+V0//EN
    [Google Scholar]
  57. Gabrielsen TS, Sørgard L 2007. Private labels, price rivalry, and public policy. Eur. Econ. Rev. 51:403–24
    [Google Scholar]
  58. Genesove D, Mullin WP 1998. Testing oligopoly models: conduct and cost in the sugar industry, 1890–1914. RAND J. Econ. 29:355–77
    [Google Scholar]
  59. Giulietti M, Waterson M 1997. Multiproduct firms’ pricing behaviour in the Italian grocery trade. Rev. Ind. Org. 12:817–32
    [Google Scholar]
  60. Glauben T, Hansen K, Loy J-P, Weiss CR 2011. Breadth and depth of promotional sales in food retailing. Agric. Econ. 57:145–49
    [Google Scholar]
  61. Gopinath G, Gourinchas P-O, Hsieh C-T, Li N 2011. International prices, costs, and markup differences. Am. Econ. Rev. 101:2450–86
    [Google Scholar]
  62. Guo Q, Wang HH, Chen Y 2016. Do Chinese dairy firms have market power? An estimation of market power with price heterogeneity. China Agric. Econ. Rev. 8:206–14
    [Google Scholar]
  63. Hao DM, Wang XQ 2003. Market power and a locative efficiency loss in Chinese tobacco industry. J. Ind. Econ. 1:152–62
    [Google Scholar]
  64. Hausman J, Leibtag E 2007. Consumer benefits from increased competition in shopping outlets: measuring the effect of Wal-Mart. J. App. Econom. 22:1157–77
    [Google Scholar]
  65. Holloway GJ 1991. The farm-retail price spread in an imperfectly competitive food industry. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 73:979–89
    [Google Scholar]
  66. Hotelling H 1929. Stability in competition. Econ. J. 39:41–57
    [Google Scholar]
  67. Hovhannisyan V, Gould BW 2012. A structural model of the analysis of retail market power: the case of fluid milk. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 94:67–79
    [Google Scholar]
  68. Hu D, Reardon T, Rozelle S, Timmer P, Wang H 2004. The emergence of supermarkets with Chinese characteristics: challenges and opportunities for China's agricultural development. Dev. Policy Rev. 22:557–86
    [Google Scholar]
  69. Hyde CE, Perloff JM 1995. Can market power be estimated?. Rev. Ind. Org. 10:465–85
    [Google Scholar]
  70. Inderst R, Shaffer G 2004. Retail mergers, buyer power and product variety. Econ. J. 117:45–67
    [Google Scholar]
  71. Inderst R, Wey C 2003. Bargaining, mergers, and technology choice in bilaterally oligopolistic industries. RAND J. Econ. 34:1–19
    [Google Scholar]
  72. Inderst R, Wey C 2007. Buyer power and supplier incentives. Eur. Econ. Rev. 51:647–67
    [Google Scholar]
  73. Inderst R, Wey C 2011. Countervailing power and dynamic efficiency. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 9:702–20
    [Google Scholar]
  74. Innes R, Hamilton SF 2006. Naked slotting fees for vertical control of multi-product retail markets. Int. J. Ind. Org. 24:303–18
    [Google Scholar]
  75. Innes R, Hamilton SF 2009. Vertical restraints and horizontal control. RAND J. Econ. 40:120–43
    [Google Scholar]
  76. Innes R, Hamilton SF 2013. Slotting allowances under supermarket oligopoly. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 95:1216–22
    [Google Scholar]
  77. Iozzi A, Valletti T 2014. Vertical bargaining and countervailing power. Am. Econ. J. Microecon. 6:106–35
    [Google Scholar]
  78. Jacenko A, Gunasekera D 2005. Australia's retail food sector: some preliminary observations ABARE Conf. Pap. 05.11 Aust. Bur. Agric. Resour. Econ Canberra:
    [Google Scholar]
  79. Jaravel X 2016. The unequal gains from product innovations: evidence from the U.S. retail sector Work. Pap., Harvard Univ https://ssrn.com/abstract=2709088
    [Google Scholar]
  80. Jumah A 2004. The long run, market power and retail pricing. Empir. Econ. 29:605–20
    [Google Scholar]
  81. Kaiser HM, Suzuki N 2006. New empirical industrial organization theories and their application to food system analysis. New Empirical Industrial Organization and the Food System HM Kaiser, N Suzuki 3–61 New York: Peter Lang
    [Google Scholar]
  82. Karp LS, Perloff JM 1996. A dynamic model of oligopoly in the coffee export market. Agricultural Markets: Mechanisms, Failures and Regulations D Martimort 171–204 Amsterdam: North Holland
    [Google Scholar]
  83. Katchova AL, Sheldon IM, Miranda MU 2005. A dynamic model of oligopoly and oligopsony in the U.S. potato processing industry. Agribusiness 21:409–28
    [Google Scholar]
  84. Klemperer P 1992. Equilibrium product lines: competing head-to-head may be less competitive. Am. Econ. Rev 82:740–55
    [Google Scholar]
  85. Kumbhakar SC, Baardsen S, Lien G 2012. A new method for estimating market power with an application to Norwegian sawmilling. Rev. Ind. Org. 40:109–29
    [Google Scholar]
  86. Liu DJ, Sun CH, Kaiser HM 1995. Market conduct under government price intervention in the U.S. dairy industry. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 20:301–15
    [Google Scholar]
  87. Lopez RA, He X, Azzam A 2017. Stochastic frontier estimation of market power in the food industries. J. Agric. Econ. 69:3–17
    [Google Scholar]
  88. Ma M, Saitone TL, Volpe R, Sexton RJ, Saksena M 2017. Market concentration, market shares, and retail food prices: evidence from the U.S. Women, Infants, and Children program Work. Pap: Univ. Calif., Davis
    [Google Scholar]
  89. Martinez SW 2007. The U.S. food system: recent developments, 1997–2006 Res. Rep. 42 US Dep. Agric., Econ. Res. Serv Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  90. McCorriston S 2014. Background note. Competition Issues in the Food Chain Industry9–46 Paris: OECD
    [Google Scholar]
  91. McDonald JM 2015. Trends in agricultural contracting. Choices 30:1–6
    [Google Scholar]
  92. McDonald JM, Korb P 2011. Agricultural contracting update: contracts in 2008 Econ. Inf. Bull. 72 US Dep. Agric., Econ. Res. Serv Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  93. Mehta N 2007. Investigating consumers’ purchase incidence and brand choice decisions across multiple product categories: a theoretical and empirical analysis. Mark. Sci. 26:196–217
    [Google Scholar]
  94. Mérel PR 2009. Measuring market power in the French Comté cheese market. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 36:31–51
    [Google Scholar]
  95. Mérel PR, Sexton RJ 2017. Buyer power with atomistic upstream entry: can downstream consolidation increase production and welfare?. Int. J. Ind. Org. 50:259–93
    [Google Scholar]
  96. Milford AB 2012. The pro-competitive effect of coffee cooperatives in Chiapas. Mexico J. Agric. Food Ind. Org. 10. https://doi.org/10.1515/1542-0485.1362
    [Crossref] [Google Scholar]
  97. Morrison Paul CJ 2001. Market and cost structure in the U.S. beef packing industry: a plant-level analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 83:64–76
    [Google Scholar]
  98. Moschini G 2010. Competition issues in the seed industry and the role of intellectual property. Choices Mag http://www.choicesmagazine.org/magazine/article.php?article=120
    [Google Scholar]
  99. Moss DL 2009. Transgenic seed platforms: competition between a rock and a hard place? Rep., Am. Antitrust Inst Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  100. Mussa M, Rosen S 1978. Monopoly and product quality. J. Econ. Theory 18:301–17
    [Google Scholar]
  101. Muth MK, Brester G, Del Roccili J, Koontz S, Martin B et al. 2005. Spot and alternative marketing arrangements in the livestock and meat industries: interim report US Dep. Agric., Grain Insp. Pack. Stock. Admin Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  102. Myers R, Sexton RJ, Tomek W 2010. A century of research on agricultural markets. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 92:376–402
    [Google Scholar]
  103. Nevo A 2001. Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica 69:307–42
    [Google Scholar]
  104. Nicholls WH 1941. A Theoretical Analysis of Imperfect Competition with Special Application to the Agricultural Industries Ames: Iowa State Coll. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  105. OECD (Organ. Econ. Coop. Dev.). 2014. Competition Issues in the Food Chain Industry Paris: OECD
    [Google Scholar]
  106. Osborne T 2005. Imperfect competition in agricultural markets: evidence from Ethiopia. J. Dev. Econ. 76:405–28
    [Google Scholar]
  107. Otsuka K, Nakano Y, Takahashi K 2016. Contract farming in developing and developed economies. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 8:353–76
    [Google Scholar]
  108. Perekhozhuk O, Glauben T, Grings M, Teuber R 2017. Approaches and methods for the econometric analysis of market power. J. Econ. Surv. 31:303–25
    [Google Scholar]
  109. Perloff JM, Karp LS, Golan A 2007. Estimating Market Power and Strategies New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  110. Piyapromdee S, Hillberry R, MacLaren D 2014. ‘Fair Trade’ coffee and the mitigation of local oligopsony power. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 41:537–59
    [Google Scholar]
  111. Puller SL 2009. Estimation of competitive conduct when firms are efficiently colluding: addressing the Corts critique. App. Econ. Lett. 16:1497–500
    [Google Scholar]
  112. Raper KC, Love HA, Shumway CR 2007. Distinguishing the source of market power. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 89:78–90
    [Google Scholar]
  113. Reardon T, Berdegué JA 2002. The rapid rise of supermarkets in Latin America: challenges and opportunities for development. Dev. Policy Rev. 20:317–34
    [Google Scholar]
  114. Reardon T, Timmer CP 2007. The supermarket revolution with Asian characteristics. Reasserting the Rural Development Agenda: Lessons Learned and Emerging Challenges in Asia AM Balisacan, N Fuwa 369–94 Singapore: IEAS
    [Google Scholar]
  115. Reardon T, Timmer CP, Barrett CB, Berdegué JA 2003.a The rise of supermarkets in Africa, Asia, and Latin America. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 85:1140–46
    [Google Scholar]
  116. Reardon T, Timmer CP, Berdegué JA 2003.b The rise of supermarkets in Latin America and Asia: implications for international markets for fruits and vegetables. Global Markets for High Value Food Products A Regmi, M. Gelhar. Agric. Inf. Bull., US Dep Agric., Econ. Res. Serv Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  117. Reimer JJ 2004. Market conduct in the U.S. ready-to-eat cereal industry. J. Agric. Food Ind. Org. 2:1075–1104
    [Google Scholar]
  118. Reiss PC, Wolak FA 2007. Structural econometric modeling: rationales and examples from industrial organization. In Handbook of Econometrics 6 (Part A), JJ Heckman, EE Leamer 4277–4415
    [Google Scholar]
  119. Richards TJ 2006. Sales by multi-product retailers. Manag. Decis. Econ. 27:261–77
    [Google Scholar]
  120. Richards TJ, Allender WJ, Hamilton SF 2012. Commodity price inflation, retail pass-through and market power. Int. J. Ind. Org. 30:50–57
    [Google Scholar]
  121. Richards TJ, Hamilton SF, Patterson PM 2010. Spatial competition and private labels. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 35:183–208
    [Google Scholar]
  122. Richards TJ, Patterson PM 2004. Slotting allowances as real options: an alternative explanation. J. Bus. 77:675–96
    [Google Scholar]
  123. Richards TJ, Pofahl G 2010. Pricing power by supermarket retailers: a ghost in the machine?. Choices 25: http://www.choicesmagazine.org/magazine/article.php?article=126
    [Google Scholar]
  124. Rogers RT 2001. Structural change in U.S. food manufacturing, 1958–1997. Agribusiness 17:3–32
    [Google Scholar]
  125. Russell GJ, Petersen A 2000. Analysis of cross category dependence in market basket selection. J. Retail. 76:367–92
    [Google Scholar]
  126. Saitone TL, Sexton RJ 2012. Market structure and competition in the U.S. food industries: implications for the 2012 Farm Bill. American Boondoggle: Fixing the Farm Bill Content V Smith, B Goodwin 1–16 Washington, DC: Am. Enterp. Inst
    [Google Scholar]
  127. Saitone TL, Sexton RJ 2017. Agri-food supply chain: evolution and performance with conflicting consumer and societal demands. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 44:634–57
    [Google Scholar]
  128. Saitone TL, Sexton RJ, Sumner DA 2015. What happens when food marketers require restrictive farming practices. ? Am. J. Agric. Econ. 97:1021–43
    [Google Scholar]
  129. Schroeter JR 1988. Estimating the degree of market power in the beef packing industry. Rev. Econ. Stat. 70:158–62
    [Google Scholar]
  130. Schroeter JR, Azzam A 1990. Measuring market power in multi-product oligopolies: the US meat industry. App. Econ. 73:1365–76
    [Google Scholar]
  131. Schroeter JR, Azzam AM, Zhang M 2000. Measuring market power in bilateral oligopoly: the wholesale market for beef. South. Econ. J. 66:526–47
    [Google Scholar]
  132. Sckokai P, Soregaroli C, Moro D 2013. Estimating market power by retailers in a dynamic framework: the Italian PDO cheese market. J. Agric. Econ. 64:33–53
    [Google Scholar]
  133. Sexton RJ 2013. Market power, misconceptions, and modern agricultural markets. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 95:209–19
    [Google Scholar]
  134. Sexton RJ, Sheldon I, McCorriston S, Wang H 2007. Agricultural trade liberalization and economic development: the role of downstream market power. Agric. Econ. 36:253–70
    [Google Scholar]
  135. Shaffer G 2005. Slotting allowances and optimal product variety. Adv. Econ. Anal. Policy 5:1083–118
    [Google Scholar]
  136. Shcherbakov O, Wakamori N 2017. Identifying the degree of collusion under proportional reduction Bank Can. Staff Work. Pap2017–51 Ottawa:
    [Google Scholar]
  137. Sheldon IM 2016. The competitiveness of agricultural product and input markets: a review and synthesis of recent research. J. Agric. App. Econ. 49:1–44
    [Google Scholar]
  138. Sheldon IM, Sperling R 2003. Estimating the extent of imperfect competition in the food industry: What have we learned. ? J. Agric. Econ. 54:89–109
    [Google Scholar]
  139. Si W 2005. Sugar industry in China: price, cost and technology efficiency PhD Thesis, China Agric Univ., Beijing:
    [Google Scholar]
  140. Singh VP, Hansen K, Gupta S 2005. Modeling preferences for common attributes in multicategory brand choice. J. Mark. Res. 42:195–209
    [Google Scholar]
  141. Smith H 2004. Supermarket choice and supermarket competition. Rev. Econ. Stud. 71:235–63
    [Google Scholar]
  142. Smith H, Hay D 2005. Streets, malls and supermarkets. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 14:29–59
    [Google Scholar]
  143. Song I, Chintagunta PK 2006. Measuring cross-category price effects with aggregate store data. Manag. Sci. 52:1594–609
    [Google Scholar]
  144. Statista. 2017. Market share of U.S. food and beverage purchases in 2016, by company. The Statistics Portal, accessed May 5. https://www.statista.com/statistics/240481/food-market-share-of-the-leading-food-retailers-of-north-america/
    [Google Scholar]
  145. Sullivan M 1997. Slotting allowances and the market for new products. J. Law Econ. 40:461–93
    [Google Scholar]
  146. Swinnen J, Vandeplas A 2011. Rich consumers and poor producers: quality and rent distribution in global value chains. J. Glob. Dev. 2:1–28
    [Google Scholar]
  147. Swinnen J, Vandeplas A 2014. Price transmission and market power in modern agricultural value chains Discuss. Pap. 347/2014, LICOS Cent Inst. Econ. Perform Leuven, Belg:
    [Google Scholar]
  148. Swinnen JFM, Vandeplas A 2010. Market power and rents in global supply chains. Agric. Econ. 41:109–20
    [Google Scholar]
  149. Thomassen Ø, Smith H, Seiler S, Schiraldi P 2017. Multi-category competition and market power: a model of supermarket pricing. Am. Econ. Rev. 107:2308–51
    [Google Scholar]
  150. USDA (US Dep. Agric.). 2017. Percent of consumer expenditures spent on food, alcoholic beverages, and tobacco that were consumed at home, by selected countries, 2014 USDA Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  151. US DOJ (US Dep. Justice). 2010. Horizontal merger guidelines. August 19 US DOJ Washington, DC: https://www.justice.gov/atr/horizontal-merger-guidelines-08192010
    [Google Scholar]
  152. US DOJ (US Dep. Justice). 2012. Competition and agriculture: voices from the workshops on agriculture and antitrust enforcement in our 21st century economy. Thoughts on the way forward Rep., US DOJ Washington, DC: https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2012/05/16/283291.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  153. US GAO (US Gov. Account. Off.). 2009. Concentration in Agriculture GAO-09–746R US GAO Washington, DC: http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d09746r.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  154. Vavra P 2009. Role, usage and motivation for contracting in agriculture Work. Pap. 16 OECD Dir. Food Agric. Fish Paris:
    [Google Scholar]
  155. Ver Ploeg M, Mancino L, Todd JE, Clay DM, Scharadin B 2015. Where do Americans usually shop for food and how do they travel to get there? Initial findings from the national household food acquisition and purchase survey Econ. Inf. Bull. 138 US Dep. Agric., Econ. Res. Serv Washington, DC:
    [Google Scholar]
  156. Villas-Boas SB 2007. Vertical relationships between manufacturers and retailers: inference with limited data. Rev. Econ. Stud. 74:625–52
    [Google Scholar]
  157. Villas-Boas SB 2009. An empirical investigation of the welfare effects of banning wholesale price discrimination. RAND J. Econ. 40:20–46
    [Google Scholar]
  158. Volpe RJ, Lavoie N 2008. The effect of Wal-Mart supercenters on grocery prices in New England. App. Econ. Perspect. Policy 30:4–26
    [Google Scholar]
  159. von Ungern-Sternberg T 1996. Countervailing power revisited. Int. J. Ind. Org. 14:507–20
    [Google Scholar]
  160. Wann JJ, Sexton RJ 1992. Imperfect competition in multiproduct food industries with application to pear processing. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 74:980–90
    [Google Scholar]
  161. Wu SY 2014. Adapting contract theory to fit contract farming. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 96:1241–56
    [Google Scholar]
  162. Xia T, Sexton RJ 2004. The competitive implications of top-of-the-market and related contract-pricing clauses. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 86:124–38
    [Google Scholar]
  163. Zheng Q, Wang HH 2017. Market power in the Chinese wine industry. Agribusiness 33:30–42
    [Google Scholar]
  164. Zheng X, Vukina T 2009. Do alternative marketing arrangements increase pork packers’ market power. ? Am. J. Agric. Econ. 91:250–63
    [Google Scholar]
  165. Zhou M, Wang L 2012. An estimation of market power and monopoly loss under product heterogeneity: an application of a new empirical industrial organization method to the liquor industry. China Indus. Econ. 6:120–32
    [Google Scholar]
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100517-023312
Loading
  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error