1932

Abstract

This review focuses on four key scholars who were instrumental in helping to launch the field of natural resource economics: Siegfried von Ciriacy-Wantrup, James Crutchfield, John Krutilla, and Anthony Scott. Their contributions include recognizing natural resources as renewable capital, thereby altering the important dynamic dimensions of an efficient allocation. The introduction of irreversibility was a key element for decisions involving unique natural assets. Introducing uncertainty into these choices required consideration of appropriate public attitudes toward risk that led to the concept of a safe minimum standard. Identifying and emphasizing the salience of nonmarket values, particularly existence and bequest benefits, gave rise to the contingent valuation and the development of stated preference methods as a cottage industry. Setting forth and evaluating alternative management policies for open access resources in a dynamic context were other achievements. The backgrounds of these four scholars shaped their professional orientation; their contributions, in turn, have shaped the evolutionary path of resource economics research.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100815-095243
2016-10-05
2024-12-10
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/resource/8/1/annurev-resource-100815-095243.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100815-095243&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Arrow KJ, Fisher AC. 1974. Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility. Q. J. Econ. 88:1312–19 [Google Scholar]
  2. Barnett HJ, Morse C. 1963. Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of Natural Resource Availability Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  3. Batabyal AA. 2014. Aspects of the management of ecological-economic systems with a safe minimum standard. Dynamic and Stochastic Resource Economics: Essays on Biodiversity, Invasive Species, Joint Systems, and Regulation AA Batabyal 199–208 Singapore: World Sci. [Google Scholar]
  4. Baumol WJ. 1967a. Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis. Am. Econ. Rev. 57:3415–26 [Google Scholar]
  5. Baumol WJ. 1967b. Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press, 2nd ed.. [Google Scholar]
  6. BC Min. Financ. Corp. Relat. 2001. British Columbia's fish production and seafood industry in the 1990s Rep., BC Min. Financ. Corp. Relat., Vancouver, BC [Google Scholar]
  7. Berrens R. 2001. The safe minimum standard of conservation and endangered species: a review. Environ. Conserv. 28:21–12 [Google Scholar]
  8. Casey K, Dewees C, Turris B, Wilen J. 1995. The effects of individual transferable harvest quotas in the British Columbia halibut fishery. Mar. Resour. Econ. 10:5211–30 [Google Scholar]
  9. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV. 1961. Water quality, a problem for the economy. J. Farm Econ. 40:51133–44 [Google Scholar]
  10. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV. 1964. The ‘new’ competition for land and some implications for public policy. Nat. Resour. J. 4:252–67 [Google Scholar]
  11. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV. 1968. Resource Conservation: Economics and Policies Berkeley: Calif. Div. Agric. Sci. [Google Scholar]
  12. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV. 1985. Natural Resource Economics: Selected Papers RC Bishop, SO Anderson Boulder, CO: Westview [Google Scholar]
  13. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV, Bishop RC. 1975. Common property as a concept in natural resources policy. Nat. Resour. J. 15:713–28 [Google Scholar]
  14. Ciriacy-Wantrup SV, Phillips WE. 1970. Conservation of the California tule elk: a socioeconomic study of a survival problem. Biol. Conserv. 3:123–32 [Google Scholar]
  15. Clark CW. 1973. Profit maximization and the extinction of animal species. J. Polit. Econ. 81:4950–61 [Google Scholar]
  16. Crutchfield JA. 1956. Common property resources and factor allocation. Can. J. Econ. Polit. Sci. 22:3292–300 [Google Scholar]
  17. Crutchfield JA. 1961. An economic evaluation of alternative methods of fishery regulations. J. Law Econ. 4:131–43 [Google Scholar]
  18. Crutchfield JA. 1962. Valuation of a fishery resource. Land Econ. 38:2145–54 [Google Scholar]
  19. Crutchfield JA. 1964. The marine fisheries: a problem in international cooperation. Am. Econ. Rev. 54:3207–18 [Google Scholar]
  20. Crutchfield JA, Zellner A. 1962. Economic Aspects of the Pacific Halibut Fishery Washington, DC: Bur. Commer. Fish. [Google Scholar]
  21. Crutchfield JA, Zellner A. 2003. The Economics of Marine Resources and Conservation Policy Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press [Google Scholar]
  22. Dasgupta PS, Heal GM. 1979. Economic Theory and Exhaustible Resources London: Cambridge Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  23. Davis RK. 1963. The value of outdoor recreation: an economic study of the Maine woods PhD Thesis, Harvard Univ. [Google Scholar]
  24. Drucker A. 2006. An application of the use of safe minimum standards in the conservation of livestock biodiversity. Environ. Dev. Econ. 11:177–94 [Google Scholar]
  25. Eckstein O. 1961. Water Resource Development: The Economics of Project Evaluation Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  26. Ely RT, Wehrwein GS. 1940. Land Economics New York: Macmillan [Google Scholar]
  27. Faustmann M. 1995 (1849). Calculation of the value which forest land and immature stands possess for forestry. J. For. Econ. 1:17–44 [Google Scholar]
  28. Freeman AM, Herriges JA, Kling CL. 2014. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Methods Washington, DC: Resour. Fut, 3rd ed.. [Google Scholar]
  29. Gordon HS. 1954. The economic theory of a common property resource: the fishery. J. Polit. Econ. 62:124–42 [Google Scholar]
  30. Gordon HS. 1956. Obstacles to agreement on control in the fishing industry. The Economics of Fisheries R Turvey, J Wiseman 65–72 Rome: Food Agric. Org. [Google Scholar]
  31. Hammond RJ. 1960. Benefit-Cost Analysis and Water Pollution Control Stanford, CA: Food Res. Inst., Stanford Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  32. Hanemann WM. 1989. Information and the concept of option value. J. Envir. Econ. Manag. 16:23–37 [Google Scholar]
  33. Hanemann WM. 1992. Preface. Pricing the European Environment S Navrud 9–36 Oslo, Nor.: Scand. Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  34. Hotelling H. 1931. The economics of exhaustible resources. J. Polit. Econ. 39:2137–75 [Google Scholar]
  35. Krutilla JV. 1967. Conservation reconsidered. Am. Econ. Rev. 57:4777–86 [Google Scholar]
  36. Krutilla JV, Cicchetti CJ. 1970. Preservation versus development: some economic issues Work. Pap., Res. Fut., Washington, DC [Google Scholar]
  37. Krutilla JV, Fisher AC. 1975. The Economics of Natural Environments: Studies in the Valuation of Commodity and Amenity Resources Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  38. Kuznets S. 1966. Modern Economic Growth New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  39. Margolis M, Nævdal E. 2008. Safe minimum standards in dynamic resource problems: conditions for living on the edge of risk. Environ. Resour. Econ. 40:3401–23 [Google Scholar]
  40. Mitra T, Roy S. 2006. Optimal exploitation of renewable resources under uncertainty and the extinction of species. Econ. Theory 28:11–23 [Google Scholar]
  41. Munro GR. 2015. Tribute to Anthony Dalton Scott. Mar. Resour. Econ. 30:439–41 [Google Scholar]
  42. Munro GR, Scott AD. 1985. The economics of fisheries management. Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics 2 AV Kneese, JL Sweeney 623–76 Amsterdam: Elsevier [Google Scholar]
  43. Musgrave RA. 1969. Cost-benefit analysis and the theory of public finance. J. Econ. Lit. 7:797–806 [Google Scholar]
  44. Nævdal E. 2012. Safe minimum standard. Berkshire Encyclopedia of Sustainability 5352–53 Great Barrington, MA: Berkshire Publ. [Google Scholar]
  45. OECD (Org. Econ. Coop. Dev.) 2012. Rebuilding fisheries: the way forward. Rep. Org. Econ. Coop. Dev., Paris [Google Scholar]
  46. Randall A. 2007. Benefit-cost analysis and a safe minimum standard of conservation. Handbook of Sustainable Development G Atkinson, S Dietz 91–108 Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar [Google Scholar]
  47. Randall A. 2011. Risk and Precaution New York: Cambridge Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  48. Scott AD. 1955a. Natural Resources: The Economics of Conservation Toronto: Univ. Toronto Press, 1st ed.. [Google Scholar]
  49. Scott AD. 1955b. The fishery: the objectives of sole ownership. J. Polit. Econ. 63:116–24 [Google Scholar]
  50. Scott AD. 1983. Natural Resources: The Economics of Conservation Montreal: McGill-Queens Univ. Press, 2nd ed.. [Google Scholar]
  51. Scott A. 2003. Price-oriented management and the Pacific halibut. See Crutchfield & Zellner 2003 184–95
  52. Scott AD. 2008. The Evolution of Resource Property Rights Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press [Google Scholar]
  53. Solomon BD, Corey-Luce CM, Halvorsen KE. 2004. The Florida manatee and eco-tourism: toward a safe minimum standard. Ecol. Econ. 50:101–15 [Google Scholar]
  54. Tollison RD. 1986. Economists as the subject of economic inquiry. South. Econ. J. 52:4909–22 [Google Scholar]
  55. Trice AH, Wood SE. 1958. Measurement of recreation benefits. Land Econ. 34:195–207 [Google Scholar]
  56. Wilen J. 2000. Renewable resource economists and policy: What difference have we made?. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 39:306–7 [Google Scholar]
  57. Wilen JE, Homans FR. 2003. Crutchfield and Zellner on exvessel price determination in the Pacific halibut fishery. See Crutchfield & Zellner 2003 196–208
  58. World Bank 2009. The Sunken Billions: The Economic Justification for Economic Reform Washington, DC: World Bank [Google Scholar]
  59. Zilberman D. 2003. The Crutchfield and Zellner monograph and the evolution of environmental and resource economics. See Crutchfield & Zellner 2003 177–84
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-100815-095243
Loading
  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error