1932

Abstract

Agricultural economists have a long history of emphasizing and analyzing the spatial dimension of agricultural and food markets. Despite a rich body of literature and important contributions to agricultural and spatial economics, one aspect is frequently disregarded: the oligopsonistic nature of agricultural markets due to spatial competition of neighboring buyers of farm products. This review presents the theoretical foundations of spatial pricing, competition, and location in terms of buyer power and discusses concepts that are relevant for agricultural markets. By providing a comprehensive overview of prior work, we highlight the multifaceted areas of applications to agricultural markets. Additionally, we discuss future research avenues for and challenges of the analysis of spatial competition in agricultural economics.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-110220-010922
2021-10-05
2024-12-09
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/resource/13/1/annurev-resource-110220-010922.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-110220-010922&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Adams B, Williams KR. 2019. Zone pricing in retail oligopoly. Am. Econ. J. Microecon. 11:124–56
    [Google Scholar]
  2. Albæk S, Schultz C. 1998. On the relative advantage of cooperatives. Econ. Lett. 59:397–401
    [Google Scholar]
  3. Alvarez AM, Fidalgo EG, Sexton RJ, Zhang MX. 2000. Oligopsony power with uniform spatial pricing: Theory and application to milk processing in Spain. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 27:347–64
    [Google Scholar]
  4. AMTF (Agric. Mark. Task Force) 2016. Improving Market Outcomes: Enhancing the Position of Farmers in the Supply Chain Report of the Agricultural Markets Task Force (ATMF) Brussels: Eur. Comm https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/default/files/food-farming-fisheries/farming/documents/amtf-report-improving-markets-outcomes_en.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  5. Anderson SP, Neven DJ. 1991. Cournot competition yields spatial agglomeration. Int. Econ. Rev. 32:793–808
    [Google Scholar]
  6. Anselin L. 1988. Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models, Vol. 4 Dordrecht: Springer
    [Google Scholar]
  7. Azzam A, Andersson H. 2008. Measuring price effects of concentration in mixed oligopoly: an application to the Swedish beef-slaughter industry. J. Ind. Competit. Trade 8:21–31
    [Google Scholar]
  8. Bailey DV, Brorsen BW, Thomsen MR. 1995. Identifying buyer market areas and the impact of buyer concentration in feeder cattle markets using mapping and spatial statistics. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 77:309–18
    [Google Scholar]
  9. Baldoni E, Esposti R. 2021. Agricultural productivity in space: an econometric assessment based on farm-level data. Am. J. Agric. Econ 103:4152544
    [Google Scholar]
  10. Balmann A. 1997. Farm-based modelling of regional structural change: a cellular automata approach. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 24:85–108
    [Google Scholar]
  11. Barton D. 1989. What is a cooperative?. Cooperatives in Agriculture DW Cobia 1–20 Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall
    [Google Scholar]
  12. Beckmann M. 1973. Spatial oligopoly as a noncooperative game. Int. J. Game Theory 2:263–68
    [Google Scholar]
  13. Beckmann M. 1976. Spatial price policies revisited. Bell J. Econ. 7:619–30
    [Google Scholar]
  14. Beckmann M, Thisse JF. 1986. The location of production activities. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Vol. 1 P Nijkamp 21–95 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  15. Beckmann MJ, Ingene CA. 1976. The profit equivalence of mill and uniform pricing policies. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 6:327–29
    [Google Scholar]
  16. Benson BL. 1980. Löschian competition under alternative demand conditions. Am. Econ. Rev. 70:1098–105
    [Google Scholar]
  17. Benson BL, Faminow MD, Fik TJ. 1992. Conduct in spatial markets: an empirical analysis of spatial pricing behavior. Pap. Reg. Sci. 71:15–30
    [Google Scholar]
  18. Benson BL, Greenhut ML, Norman G. 1990. On the basing-point system. Am. Econ. Rev. 80:584–88
    [Google Scholar]
  19. Berger T. 2001. Agent-based spatial models applied to agriculture: a simulation tool for technology diffusion, resource use changes and policy analysis. Agric. Econ. 25:245–60
    [Google Scholar]
  20. Bergquist LF, Dinerstein M. 2020. Competition and entry in agricultural markets: experimental evidence from Kenya. Am. Econ. Rev. 110:3705–47
    [Google Scholar]
  21. Berry S, Levinsohn J, Pakes A. 1995. Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica 63:841–90
    [Google Scholar]
  22. Biscaia R, Mota I. 2013. Models of spatial competition: a critical review. Pap. Reg. Sci. 92:851–71
    [Google Scholar]
  23. Bliss C. 1988. A theory of retail pricing. J. Ind. Econ. 36:375–91
    [Google Scholar]
  24. Bonanno A, Russo C, Menapace L. 2018. Market power and bargaining in agrifood markets: a review of emerging topics and tools. Agribusiness 34:6–23
    [Google Scholar]
  25. Brenner S. 2005. Hotelling games with three, four and more players. J. Reg. Sci. 45:851–64
    [Google Scholar]
  26. Capozza DR, Van Order R. 1978. A generalized model of spatial competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 68:896–908
    [Google Scholar]
  27. Cheung FK, Wang X. 1996. Mill and uniform pricing: a comparison. J. Reg. Sci. 36:129–43
    [Google Scholar]
  28. Chomitz KM, Gray DA. 1996. Roads, land use, and deforestation: a spatial model applied to Belize. World Bank Econ. Rev. 10:487–512
    [Google Scholar]
  29. Cohen JP, Paul CJM. 2005. Agglomeration economies and industry location decisions: the impacts of spatial and industrial spillovers. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 35:215–37
    [Google Scholar]
  30. Cook ML. 1995. The future of US agricultural cooperatives: a neo-institutional approach. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 77:1153–59
    [Google Scholar]
  31. Cotterill RW. 1987. Agricultural cooperatives: a unified theory of pricing, finance, and investment. Cooperative Theory: New Approaches JS Royer, Serv. Rep 18171–258 Washington, DC: US Dep. Agric.
    [Google Scholar]
  32. Courtois P, Subervie J. 2015. Farmer bargaining power and market information services. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 97:953–77
    [Google Scholar]
  33. d'Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse JF 1979. On Hotelling's “Stability in Competition.”. Econometrica 47:1145–50
    [Google Scholar]
  34. De Palma A, Ginsburgh V, Papageorgiou YY, Thisse JF. 1985. The principle of minimum differentiation holds under sufficient heterogeneity. Econometrica 53:767–81
    [Google Scholar]
  35. Dobson PW, Waterson M, Davies SW. 2003. The patterns and implications of increasing concentration in European food retailing. J. Agric. Econ. 54:111–25
    [Google Scholar]
  36. Durham CA, Sexton RJ. 1992. Oligopsony potential in agriculture: residual supply estimation in California processing tomato market. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 74:962–72
    [Google Scholar]
  37. Durham CA, Sexton RJ, Song JH. 1996. Spatial competition, uniform pricing, and transportation efficiency in the California processing tomato industry. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 78:115–25
    [Google Scholar]
  38. Eaton C, Lipsey R. 1975. The principle of minimum differentiation reconsidered: some new developments in the theory of spatial competition. Rev. Econ. Stud. 42:27–49
    [Google Scholar]
  39. Economides N. 1993. Hotelling's “main street” with more than two competitors. J. Reg. Sci. 33:303–19
    [Google Scholar]
  40. Espinosa MP. 1992. Delivered pricing, FOB pricing and collusion in spatial markets. Rand J. Econ. 23:64–85
    [Google Scholar]
  41. Fackler PL, Goodwin BK. 2001. Spatial price analysis. In Handbook of Agricultural EconomicsVol. 1:Part Bed. BL Gardner, GC Rausserpp. 9711024 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  42. Fafchamps M, Hill RV. 2005. Selling at the farmgate or traveling to market. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 87:717–34
    [Google Scholar]
  43. Faminow MD, Benson BL. 1990. Integration of spatial markets. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 72:49–62
    [Google Scholar]
  44. Fousekis P. 2011a. Free-on-board and uniform delivery pricing strategies in a mixed duopsony. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 38:119–39
    [Google Scholar]
  45. Fousekis P. 2011b. Spatial price competition between cooperatives under Hotelling–Smithies conjectures. Agric. Econ. Rev. 12:5–15
    [Google Scholar]
  46. Fousekis P. 2015. Location equilibria in a mixed duopsony with a cooperative. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 59:518–32
    [Google Scholar]
  47. Fousekis P. 2016. Member coordination costs and spatial entry deterrence in a mixed duopsony with a cooperative. Spat. Econ. Anal. 11:340–54
    [Google Scholar]
  48. Fulton M, Giannakas K. 2013. The future of agricultural cooperatives. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 5:61–91
    [Google Scholar]
  49. Gallagher P, Wisner R, Brubacker H. 2005. Price relationships in processors’ input market areas: testing theories for corn prices near ethanol plants. Can. J. Agric. Econ. 53:117–39
    [Google Scholar]
  50. Grashuis J. 2020. The competitive impact of cooperatives on the spot market: a spatial analysis of Iowa corn prices. J. Agric. Food Ind. Organ. 18:20190063
    [Google Scholar]
  51. Grashuis J, Su Y. 2019. A review of the empirical literature on farmer cooperatives: performance, ownership and governance, finance, and member attitude. Ann. Public Coop. Econ. 90:77–102
    [Google Scholar]
  52. Graubner M. 2010. The spatial dimension of pricing and competition in agricultural markets. Doctoral Thesis Martin-Luther-Univ. Halle-Wittenberg Halle (Saale), Ger.:
    [Google Scholar]
  53. Graubner M. 2018. Lost in space? The effect of direct payments on land rental prices. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ 45:143–71
    [Google Scholar]
  54. Graubner M. 2020. Spatial monopoly pricing under non-constant marginal costs. Lett. Spat. Resour. Sci. 13:81–97
    [Google Scholar]
  55. Graubner M, Balmann A, Sexton RJ. 2011a. Spatial price discrimination in agricultural product procurement markets: a computational economics approach. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 93:949–67
    [Google Scholar]
  56. Graubner M, Koller I, Salhofer K, Balmann A. 2011b. Cooperative versus non-cooperative spatial competition for milk. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 38:99–118
    [Google Scholar]
  57. Graubner M, Ostapchuk I, Gagalyuk T. 2021. Agroholdings and land rental markets: a spatial competition perspective. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 48:158–206
    [Google Scholar]
  58. Greenhut ML. 1981. Spatial pricing in the United States, West Germany and Japan. Econ. New Ser 48:79–86
    [Google Scholar]
  59. Greenhut ML, Hwang M, Ohta H. 1975. Observations on the shape and relevance of the spatial demand function. Econometrica 43:669–82
    [Google Scholar]
  60. Greenhut ML, Norman G, Hung CS 1987. The Economics of Imperfect Competition: A Spatial Approach Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press. , 2nd ed..
    [Google Scholar]
  61. Gronberg T, Meyer J. 1981. Competitive equilibria in uniform delivered pricing models. Am. Econ. Rev. 71:758–63
    [Google Scholar]
  62. Gupta B, Lai FC, Pal D, Sarkar J, Yu CM. 2004. Where to locate in a circular city?. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 22:759–82
    [Google Scholar]
  63. Häckner J. 1996. Optimal symmetric punishments in a Bertrand differentiated products duopoly. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 14:611–30
    [Google Scholar]
  64. Hamilton JH, Thisse JF, Weskamp A. 1989. Spatial discrimination: Bertrand versus Cournot in a model of location choice. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 19:87–102
    [Google Scholar]
  65. Hamilton SF, Liaukonyte J, Richards TJ. 2020. Pricing strategies of food retailers. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 12:87–110
    [Google Scholar]
  66. Hansen P, Peeters D, Thisse JF. 1997. Facility location under zone pricing. J. Reg. Sci. 37:1–22
    [Google Scholar]
  67. Happe K, Kellermann K, Balmann A. 2006. Agent-based analysis of agricultural policies: an illustration of the agricultural policy simulator AgriPoliS, its adaptation and behavior. Ecol. Soc. 11:49
    [Google Scholar]
  68. Hinloopen J, van Marrewijk C. 1999. On the limits and possibilities of the principle of minimum differentiation. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 17:735–50
    [Google Scholar]
  69. Hobbs BF. 1986. Mill pricing versus spatial price discrimination under Bertrand and Cournot spatial competition. J. Ind. Econ. 35:173–91
    [Google Scholar]
  70. Holahan W. 1975. The welfare effects of spatial price discrimination. Am. Econ. Rev. 65:498–503
    [Google Scholar]
  71. Hoover EM. 1937. Spatial price discrimination. Rev. Econ. Stud. 4:182–91
    [Google Scholar]
  72. Hotelling H. 1929. Stability in competition. Econ. J. 39:41–57
    [Google Scholar]
  73. Houde JF. 2012. Spatial differentiation and vertical mergers in retail markets for gasoline. Am. Econ. Rev. 102:2147–82
    [Google Scholar]
  74. Hovenkamp H. 2007. Standards ownership and competition policy. Boston Coll. Law Rev. 48:87–109
    [Google Scholar]
  75. Hsu S. 1997. The agroindustry: a neglected aspect of the location theory of manufacturing. J. Reg. Sci. 37:259–74
    [Google Scholar]
  76. Hsu S. 2006. Simple monopoly price theory in a spatial market. Ann. Reg. Sci. 40:531–44
    [Google Scholar]
  77. Iozzi A. 2004. Spatial duopoly under uniform delivered pricing when firms avoid turning customers away. Ann. Reg. Sci. 38:513–29
    [Google Scholar]
  78. Irmen A, Thisse JF. 1998. Competition in multi-characteristics spaces: Hotelling was almost right. J. Econ. Theory 78:76–102
    [Google Scholar]
  79. Irwin E, Isserman A, Kilkenny M, Partridge M. 2011. A century of research on rural development and regional issues. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 92:522–53
    [Google Scholar]
  80. Judd KL. 1994. Computational economics and economic theory: Substitutes or complements?. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 21:907–42
    [Google Scholar]
  81. Jung J, Sesmero J, Siebert R. 2020. Spatial differentiation and market power in input procurement: evidence from a structural model of the corn market CESifo Work. Pap 8088.CESifo, Munich https://www.cesifo.org/node/52594
    [Google Scholar]
  82. Kats A. 1995. More on Hotelling's stability in competition. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 13:89–93
    [Google Scholar]
  83. Kats A, Thisse JF. 1989. Spatial oligopolies with uniform delivered pricing CORE Discuss. Pap. 8903 Univ. Leuven, Belg https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:cor:louvco:1989003
    [Google Scholar]
  84. Krugman P. 1998. Space: the final frontier. J. Econ. Perspect. 12:161–74
    [Google Scholar]
  85. Kuenne RE. 1992. The Economics of Oligopolistic Competition Oxford, UK: Blackwell. , 2nd ed..
    [Google Scholar]
  86. Lambert DM, Wilcox MD, English A, Stewart LA. 2008. Ethanol plant location determinants and county comparative advantage. J. Agric. Appl. Econ. 40:117–35
    [Google Scholar]
  87. Lederer P, Hurter APJ. 1986. Competition of firms: discriminatory pricing and location. Econometrica 54:623–40
    [Google Scholar]
  88. Leistritz FL. 1992. Agribusiness firms: location determinants and economic contribution. Agribusiness 8:273–86
    [Google Scholar]
  89. LeSage JP, Pace RK. 2009. Introduction to Spatial Econometrics Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press
    [Google Scholar]
  90. LeVay C. 1983. Agricultural co-operative theory: a review. J. Agric. Econ. 34:1–44
    [Google Scholar]
  91. Liang Q, Hendrikse G. 2016. Pooling and the yardstick effect of cooperatives. Agric. Syst. 143:97–105
    [Google Scholar]
  92. Löfgren KG. 1985. The pricing of pulpwood and spatial price discrimination: theory and practice. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 12:283–93
    [Google Scholar]
  93. Löfgren KG. 1986. The spatial monopsony: a theoretical analysis. J. Reg. Sci. 26:707–30
    [Google Scholar]
  94. Lopez RA, Henderson NR. 1989. The determinants of location choices for food processing plants. Agribusiness 5:619–32
    [Google Scholar]
  95. Lucas MT, Chhajed D. 2004. Applications of location analysis in agriculture: a survey. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 55:561–78
    [Google Scholar]
  96. McNew K, Griffith D. 2005. Measuring the impact of ethanol plants on local grain prices. Rev. Agric. Econ. 27:164–80
    [Google Scholar]
  97. Mérel PR, Sexton RJ. 2010. Kinked-demand equilibria and weak duopoly in the Hotelling model of horizontal differentiation. BE J. Theor. Econ. 10:12
    [Google Scholar]
  98. Mérel PR, Sexton RJ, Suzuki A. 2009. Optimal investment in transportation infrastructure when middlemen have market power: a developing-country analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 91:462–76
    [Google Scholar]
  99. Miklos-Thal J. 2008. Delivered pricing and the impact of spatial differentiation on cartel stability. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 26:1365–80
    [Google Scholar]
  100. Miller NH, Osborne M. 2014. Spatial differentiation and price discrimination in the cement industry: evidence from a structural model. RAND J. Econ. 45:221–47
    [Google Scholar]
  101. Motamed M, McPhail L, Williams R. 2016. Corn area response to local ethanol markets in the United States: a grid cell level analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 98:726–43
    [Google Scholar]
  102. Nevo A. 2001. Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica 69:307–42
    [Google Scholar]
  103. Norman G. 1981. Spatial competition and spatial price discrimination. Rev. Econ. Stud. 48:97–111
    [Google Scholar]
  104. OECD (Organ. Econ. Co-op. Dev.) 2014. Competition Issues in the Food Chain Industry Paris: OECD https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/CompetitionIssuesintheFoodChainIndustry.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  105. Omamo SW. 1998. Transport costs and smallholder cropping choices: an application to Siaya district, Kenya. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 80:116–23
    [Google Scholar]
  106. Ortmann GF, King RP. 2007. Agricultural cooperatives I: history, theory and problems. Agrekon 46:18–46
    [Google Scholar]
  107. Pal D. 1998. Does Cournot competition yield spatial agglomeration?. Econ. Lett. 60:49–53
    [Google Scholar]
  108. Pinkse J, Slade ME. 2004. Mergers, brand competition, and the price of a pint. Eur. Econ. Rev. 48:617–43
    [Google Scholar]
  109. Pinkse J, Slade ME, Brett C. 2002. Spatial price competition: a semiparametric approach. Econometrica 70:1111–53
    [Google Scholar]
  110. Proost S, Thisse JF. 2019. What can be learned from spatial economics?. J. Econ. Lit. 57:575–643
    [Google Scholar]
  111. Ravallion M. 1986. Testing market integration. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 68:102–9
    [Google Scholar]
  112. Roe B, Irwin EG, Sharp JS. 2002. Pigs in space: modeling the spatial structure of hog production in traditional and nontraditional production regions. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 84:259–78
    [Google Scholar]
  113. Rogers RT, Sexton RJ. 1994. Assessing the importance of oligopsony power in agricultural markets. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 76:1143–50
    [Google Scholar]
  114. Saint-Cyr LD, Storm H, Heckelei T, Piet L 2019. Heterogeneous impacts of neighbouring farm size on the decision to exit: evidence from Brittany. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 46:237–66
    [Google Scholar]
  115. Salop SC. 1979. Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J. Econ. 10:141–56
    [Google Scholar]
  116. Sarmiento C, Wilson WW. 2005. Spatial modeling in technology adoption decisions: the case of shuttle train elevators. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 87:1034–45
    [Google Scholar]
  117. Sarmiento C, Wilson WW, Dahl B. 2012. Spatial competition and ethanol plant location decisions. Agribusiness 28:260–73
    [Google Scholar]
  118. Scherer FM, Ross D. 1990. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. , 3rd ed..
    [Google Scholar]
  119. Schreinemachers P, Berger T. 2011. An agent-based simulation model of human–environment interactions in agricultural systems. Environ. Model. Softw. 26:845–59
    [Google Scholar]
  120. Sesmero JP, Balagtas JV, Pratt M. 2015. The economics of spatial competition for corn stover. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 40:425–41
    [Google Scholar]
  121. Sexton RJ. 1990. Imperfect competition in agricultural markets and the role of cooperatives: a spatial analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 72:709–20
    [Google Scholar]
  122. Sexton RJ. 2000. Industrialization and consolidation in the U.S. food sector: implications for competition and welfare. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 82:1087–104
    [Google Scholar]
  123. Sexton RJ, Kling CL, Carman HF. 1991. Market integration, efficiency of arbitrage, and imperfect competition: methodology and application to U.S. celery. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 73:568–80
    [Google Scholar]
  124. Sexton RJ, Lavoie N. 2001. Food processing and distribution: an industrial organization approach. In Handbook of Agricultural EconomicsVol. 1:Part Bed. BL Gardner, GC Rausserpp. 863932 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  125. Sexton RJ, Wilson BM, Wann JJ. 1989. Some tests of the economic theory of cooperatives: methodology and application to cotton ginning. West. J. Agric. Econ. 14:56–66
    [Google Scholar]
  126. Staatz JM. 1987. Recent developments in the theory of agricultural cooperation. J. Agric. Cooperation 2:74–95
    [Google Scholar]
  127. Storm H, Mittenzwei K, Heckelei T. 2015. Direct payments, spatial competition and farm survival in Norway. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 97:1192–205
    [Google Scholar]
  128. Syverson C. 2004. Market structure and productivity: a concrete example. J. Political Econ. 112:1181–222
    [Google Scholar]
  129. Tabuchi T. 1994. Two-stage two-dimensional spatial competition between two firms. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 24:207–27
    [Google Scholar]
  130. Takayama T, Judge GG. 1964. Equilibrium among spatially separated markets: a reformulation. Econometrica 32:510–24
    [Google Scholar]
  131. Tennbakk B. 1995. Marketing cooperatives in mixed duopolies. J. Agric. Econ. 46:33–45
    [Google Scholar]
  132. Tesfatsion L 2006. Agent-based computational economics: a constructive approach to economic theory. Handbook of Computational Economics L Tesfatsion, K Judd 831–80 Amsterdam: Elsevier/North Holland
    [Google Scholar]
  133. Thisse JF, Vives X. 1988. On the strategic choice of spatial price policy. Am. Econ. Rev. 78:122–37
    [Google Scholar]
  134. Tribl C. 2012. Spatial competition of food processors in pure and mixed markets under uniform delivered pricing. Doctoral Thesis Tech. Univ. München Freising, Ger.:
    [Google Scholar]
  135. Tribl C, Morawetz U, Salhofer K. 2017. Spatial competition in a mixed market: the case of milk processors. Presented at the XV EAAE Congress Towards Sustainable Agri-Food Systems: Balancing Between Markets and Society Aug. 29–Sep. 1. Parma, It.:
    [Google Scholar]
  136. US DOJ (US Dep. Justice) 2012. Competition and agriculture: voices from the workshops on agriculture and antitrust enforcement in our 21st century economy and thoughts on the way forward Rep., US Dep. Justice Washington, DC: https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2012/05/16/283291.pdf
    [Google Scholar]
  137. van Leeuwen E, Lijesen M. 2016. Agents playing Hotelling's game: an agent-based approach to a game theoretic model. Ann. Reg. Sci. 57:393–411
    [Google Scholar]
  138. Vogel J. 2011. Spatial price discrimination with heterogeneous firms. J. Ind. Econ. 59:661–76
    [Google Scholar]
  139. von Thünen JH. 1826. Der Isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalökonomie Stuttgart: Gustav Fischer
    [Google Scholar]
  140. Vroege W, Meraner M, Polman N, Storm H, Heijman W, Finger R. 2020. Beyond the single farm—a spatial econometric analysis of spill-overs in farm diversification in the Netherlands. Land Use Policy 99:105019
    [Google Scholar]
  141. Wang Y, Delgado MS, Sesmero J, Gramig BM. 2020. Market structure and the local effects of ethanol expansion on land allocation: a spatially explicit analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 102:1598–622
    [Google Scholar]
  142. Wann JJ, Sexton RJ. 1992. Imperfect competition in multiproduct food industries with application to pear processing. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 74:980–90
    [Google Scholar]
  143. Zhang M, Sexton RJ. 2001. FOB or uniform delivered prices: strategic choice and welfare effects. J. Ind. Econ. 49:197–221
    [Google Scholar]
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-110220-010922
Loading
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-resource-110220-010922
Loading

Data & Media loading...

Supplementary Data

  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error